Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T07:58:06.623Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Is archaeology conceivable within the degrowth movement?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 May 2021

Nicolas Zorzin*
Affiliation:
Institute of Archaeology, National Cheng Kung University, Tainan City, Taiwan
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Since the 1980s, archaeology has been further embedded in a reinforced and accelerating capitalist ideology, namely neo-liberalism. Most archaeologists had no alternative but to adapt to it through concessions to the free-market economy and to the so-called mitigations taking place within development. However, it is now apparent that the ongoing global socio-ecological disaster we are facing cannot be reversed with compromises but rather with a radical engagement against the injunctions of competition and growth. I suggest that we must anticipate the necessary transformations of archaeology in the coming decades, before archaeology becomes a technical avatar of the neo-liberal dogma, or before its complete annihilation for being deemed ‘superfluous’ (Wurst 2019, 171) by the capitalist regime. In this paper, I will use the idea of ‘degrowth’ to propose a new paradigm for archaeology by applying the concepts of civil disobedience, voluntary simplicity, redistribution of means and the ethics of no-growth.

Type
Discussion Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives licence(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

Opening new horizons

This contribution aims to continue the debate opened by James L. Flexner (Reference Flexner2020) in Archaeological dialogues, over the current ‘degrowth’ movement and its hypothetical impact on archaeological practices. It explores the possible outcomes of the combination of archaeology and the degrowth movement, which comes with the unavoidable preliminary task of providing a political-economy contextualization. This contextualization consists of retracing the origin of the resistance against an ideology which relies essentially on the idea of a ‘free’ competitive market economy, within which archaeology has been largely participating, from which it has benefited, and in which it has developed. To structure my arguments in this contribution I propose to (1) define succinctly the nature of this ideology, best described as ‘neo-liberalism’, before trying to (2) define a potential alternative, and (3) explore the implications of the degrowth movement in archaeology.

This article should be understood as a continuation of previous publications where I address the current configuration of the capitalist structure and its archaeological organizational expressions, mainly from a Marxist critical perspective (see Zorzin Reference Zorzin2011b; Reference Zorzin, Gnecco and Lippert2015a; Reference Zorzin2015b; Reference Zorzin2016a; Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b). I do not intend to reiterate these analyses, which concern material conditions, labour, class struggle and alienation, even though they remain in the theoretical background of this contribution. Instead, I would like to explore further and focus on the possibility of conceiving, choosing and collectively experimenting with an alternative organizational system for archaeology, inspired by what is called today the degrowth movement. Degrowth refers here to a politico-economic radical reorganization which problematizes capitalism. Degrowth shares with Marxism the idea that capitalism is simply a mode of production driven not only by growth (despite the term ‘degrowth’ – ‘deaccumulation’ would be a more accurate term), but primarily by competition for profit, and lately, by the neo-liberal ‘craze for turning over global natures … to market-oriented management’ (Moore Reference Moore2017, 177).

I am aware that ‘degrowth’ is still mainly an abstract project, rarely materialized, and that some ideas must be discussed in idealistic terms, which runs the risk of being perceived as naive, partially ungrounded or unrealistic. Yet this is precisely the aim of this contribution: to trigger ‘le réveil des imaginaires’ (the awakening of the imaginaries) (Damasio Reference Damasio2020), in opposition to the Thatcherite mantra ‘There is no alternative’. The aim is thus to induce a collective exploration, in our respective contexts, of our own imagined, necessarily troublesome, solutions, even though they can hardly be entirely satisfying until we have opportunities to put them in practice in the coming decades.

Defining or redefining a concept resisting definition: neo-liberalism

One of the main issues posed by the ideological–structural system humanity is now dominantly living in lies in its resistance to being defined (Mirowski Reference Mirowski2018; Reference Mirowski2014). Defining the contours of an idea makes it a tangible ‘thing’, which can be recognized for what it is by all and potentially identified as an ideological programme to concur with willingly or be fought against. In both cases, populations living in ‘democratic countries’ are expected to be fully aware of the aims and effects of a doctrine proposed or implemented, but the main characteristic of the current neo-liberal doctrine is precisely its denial of being one (Altman Reference Altman2005). Its claim is to be ‘above politics’ or to be ‘apolitical’, i.e. too ‘common-sense’ to be defined and seriously challenged (Hall and O’Shea Reference Hall and O’Shea2013, 8–24; Waterton and Smith Reference Waterton and Smith2009, 13; Hale Reference Hale1990, 7, in Hutchings Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018).

What exactly are we talking about when we use the term ‘neo-liberalism’? For some of its most vocal opponents, neo-liberalism has been generally defined as a ‘programme for destroying collective structures which may impede the pure market logic’ (Bourdieu Reference Bourdieu1998). More precisely, as ‘a political project carried out by the corporate capitalist class as they felt intensively threatened [from the 1920s to the 1980s], so in many respects the project was a counterrevolutionary project’ (Harvey Reference Harvey2016). It was ‘undermining unions, and other forms of association … meanwhile it was transferring decisions to unaccountable private power, all in the rhetoric of freedom’ (Chomsky in Lydon Reference Lydon2017).

On the contrary, many would continue to assert that ‘neo-liberalism’ only exists in the minds of its leftist opponents (Altman Reference Altman2005; Peck Reference Peck2013; Burns Reference Burns2014, 260; Brick Reference Brick2014, 875, in Mirowski Reference Mirowski2014, 2–3): neoliberalism ‘is a term commonly used by the left to describe the market-friendly, globalist policies’ (Lopez Reference Lopez2017). ‘This term has a wide variety of definitions and is used less frequently by its proponents (who prefer to speak of its component parts, such as free trade, privatization, deregulation and investor’s rights) than by its critics on the Left, who see it as a package of inter-related policies’ (Swift Reference Swift2014, 29–30).

Openly or not, the aim of such ideology is to transform humankind into a flexible and mobile mass, free from its stases (i.e. divested from its needs for stability, commons, protection and solidarity, thus divested from the fundamental characteristics which one could define as ‘humanity’ or as a ‘human society’), which make it unfit for the new globalized environment constituted of open, competitive and unquestionable flux and transactions (Stiegler Reference Stiegler2019b). As such, neo-liberalism can be defined as

The extension of market dominance to all spheres of social life, fostered and enforced by the state. In economic policy, this means deregulation and privatization. In culture, it means untrammelled marketing and the commoditization of everyday life, including the intimate sphere (Scialabba, cited in Radio Open Source 2017).

The main concern of a neo-liberal logic is to constantly revitalize competition at all levels in society, as a mindset. The now almost universally accepted competitive ‘rules of the game’ come with the belief in equality of opportunities to succeed for all, through unbridled struggle between everything and everyone. Neo-liberalism, as such, has been very successful, because it gives the masses a sense of purpose, within the framework of so-called ‘fair competition’ and ‘unlimited growth’. The often underestimated major achievement of the neo-liberal doctrine is indeed its cultural hegemony among populations, implemented without much visible coercion. The colonization of people’s minds has been extremely efficient. To a certain extent, we all have been neo-liberalized, in the sense that we believe consciously or unconsciously that we ‘must’ adapt to the current environment. Instead of challenging the status quo by uniting and by radically shifting our ways of life, we continue to compete within it to prosper economically (Latouche Reference Latouche2019a, 8) or to survive (Stiegler Reference Stiegler2019a).

Yet this ideology is reaching its limits faced with both the environmental crisis (Servigne and Stevens Reference Servigne and Stevens2015) and rebellions of an increasing part of the populations against what was revealed as a self-destructive ideology (Cervera-Marzal Reference Cervera-Marzal2016; Kempf Reference Kempf2009). The COVID-19 pandemic might become a catalyser for both. Yet what has been attempted globally in the fight against COVID-19 so far was only addressing an epiphenomenon resulting directly from the ecological crisis, which remains largely ignored.

Against today’s ongoing ecological and social crisis, one can observe two distinct avoidance strategies implemented by various neo-liberal governments:

  1. 1 Facing the global ecological crisis, some apply a ‘green-capitalism’ recipe, which claims that growth is entirely compatible with ecological sustainability (Tanuro Reference Tanuro2013), while others openly use denial or manipulation of facts to avoid changing privileged humanity’s self-destructive behaviours (Servigne and Stevens Reference Servigne and Stevens2015, 222–223).

  2. 2 Facing social crises fuelled by rapid impoverishment and rising inequalities, neo-liberal governments use repression and structural violence (Sizaire Reference Sizaire2019) to contain the contestations rising against the neo-liberal order.

In this very particular context, what stances, as citizens and as professionals both in archaeology and in cultural-heritage fields, can we adopt?

I believe two processes can be simultaneously engaged to thwart this new order:

  1. 1 a decolonisation of our neo-liberalised collective psyche (Chomsky Reference Chomsky2013, 185; Latouche Reference Latouche2004; Reference Latouche, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015a; Reference Latouche2019a, 36–37; Reference Latouche2019b) and

  2. 2 a grouping of communities’ radical actions, using the degrowth movement as a concrete instrument of emancipation, with global effects expected in the long term (Latouche and Jappe Reference Latouche and Jappe2015; Latouche Reference Latouche2019a; Reference Latouche2019b).

What is degrowth?

Degrowth could be defined in simple terms as a social movement advocating a global downscaling of production and consumption to face collectively both environmental disasters and social inequalities. Historically, the term ‘degrowth’ comes from French: décroissance, and was first used as such by the post-Marxist ecologist André Gorz in 1972 (Kallis, Demaria, and D’Alisa Reference Kallis, Demari, D’Alisa, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 1) as well as by Illich and Castoriadis (D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis Reference D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015). These authors were already firmly opposing the supporters of growth (it should be noted that in the 1970s–1980s, the principles of growth and progress were shared by both opposed dominant blocks, capitalist and communist). From a Marxist perspective, attitudes towards degrowth are still divided and sometimes opposed (Demaria et al. Reference Demaria, Schneider, Sekulova and Martinez-Alier2013, 206). Some orthodox interpretations of Marxist theory reject degrowth because their readings are closely embedded into ideas of progress and socio-economic growth. Furthermore, some authors, such as Altvater, seem to suggest that degrowth is not obviously opposed to capitalism but only an inevitable step in its eventual collapse (Demaria et al. Reference Demaria, Schneider, Sekulova and Martinez-Alier2013, 206, citing Altvater). Altvater makes the point that ‘reduction of growth is inevitable’, but the fundamental difference between that phenomenon as a ‘collapsing capitalism’ and a ‘degrowth movement’ is that the latter is a well-informed choice and an experimental path taken by some individuals or groups of individuals to accelerate the collapse of the neo-liberal order and prepare for a truly post-capitalist society. However, there are also neo-Marxist authors, such as David Harvey (Reference Harvey2005; Reference Harvey2016; Reference Harvey2017), who are in line with the approaches proposed by the degrowth movement.

In the end, the term ‘degrowth’ has never meant ‘declining’, ‘weakening’, ‘stagnating’, and ‘lessening’ (Latouche and Jappe Reference Latouche and Jappe2015). Instead, degrowth is a revolutionary project, in the sense that it offers a radical sea change in contrast with the competitive and growth-based society we are living in. After emerging from an unlimited growth economy, either through choice (i.e. through collective resistance or revolt), or through the coming forecasted socio-ecological disasters (Spratt and Dunlop Reference Spratt and Dunlop2019), degrowth aims to build a relatively prosperous, collegial society without growth (Jackson Reference Jackson2017). A society of degrowth is not a global alternative per se but rather a matrix of multifaceted alternatives, which mostly still need to be invented and adjusted to local (deteriorated or not) environmental and sociocultural specificities. I will now follow with a more detailed analysis of the concept of degrowth and its uses.

Degrowth as a scarecrow Often the first reaction when someone uses the term ‘degrowth’ is to compare it to an anachronistic desire to return to a Palaeolithic way of life, assuming that it will bring humanity back into stagnation at best, or as ‘cave dwellers’ at worst (American businessman Andy Kessler quoted in Pethokoukis Reference Pethokoukis2017). The term also provokes condescension, with critics presenting it as a backward-looking, outdated and regressive idea, which has already lost the fight of ‘reason’ (see Pinker Reference Pinker2018, as the champion of the high-tech ‘progressist’ forces): ‘Economic growth provides the wealth and technologies needed to lift people from poverty while simultaneously lightening humanity’s footprint on the natural world. Rather than degrowth, the planet – and especially its poor people – need more and faster economic growth’ (Bailey Reference Bailey2018, in Reason, a think-thank ultraliberal/libertarian magazine).

Another common accusation formulated against degrowth is to define it in a derogatory way as the new ‘utopia’ of our time, mostly carried out by radical environmentalists, such as Greta Thunberg, opposing the globally accepted sustainable-development ‘liberal consensus’ (Redclift Reference Redclift2005, 220). Some others consider it a utopia far too frightening because it does not yet propose concrete and clear alternative models (Schwartzman Reference Schwartzman2012, 123–124), and could incapacitate some individuals, notably through ‘eco-anxiety’ (Faubert Reference Faubert2019). Furthermore, degrowth is sometimes criticized, even by its own advocates, for being too abstract and too weak to be taken seriously, because it suffers both from the tendency to not be supported in academic writings by ‘rigid hypothesis testing’, and from an absence of analyses of ‘potentials for non-market value creation’ and identification of ‘concrete well-being benefits’ (Weiss and Cattaneo Reference Weiss and Cattaneo2017).

Among its supporters, Kallis and March (Reference Kallis and March2014) also define degrowth as a utopia because it ‘is nowhere to be seen. There is theory and there are small experiments broadly inspired by degrowth, but there is no spatialized “degrowth world” in its full plentitude’ (ibid., 2). Even though the term ‘utopia’ can be used to define degrowth, it is time to face the fact that today’s utopia (i.e. the dream of a perfect world) tends to lie exclusively in the neo-liberal dogma supporting ‘the cultural logic of a socially and environmentally unsustainable growth’ (Prádanos Reference Prádanos2018), based essentially on primitive accumulation strategies, and fuelled by archaic extracting economic surpluses. Bailey’s argument for more and faster growth (see above) is indeed the real utopia of the post-1970s world, even though its believers are in total denial of its current failure:

Today, a lack of realism no longer consists in advocating greater well-being through degrowth and the subversion of the prevailing way of life. Lack of realism consists in imagining that economic growth can still bring about increased human welfare, and indeed that it is still physically possible (Gorz Reference Gorz1980, 13).

In my view, degrowth has no utopian vocation, but rather has a transitional and inspirational function towards a no-growth society, which can only be far from perfect, because it will necessitate significant efforts and sacrifices during and after the process of transition from our current market-economic competitive-based ways of life. Ursula K. Le Guin’s fiction The dispossessed (1974) is a good illustration of this neither utopian nor harsh dystopian process. This we could define as an anarchist ‘atopia’ (Flexner (Reference Flexner2020, 160) defines it as a ‘concrete utopia’) i.e. a transformation occurring in an inhospitable Earth which cannot be turned into a prosperous dwelling (any more) but where humans survive (not thrive) in the best sustainable way, socially and ecologically. Now, and in contrast with the many critics of degrowth, what the concept might truly embed is that the dogmatic neo-liberal imaginary based on growth needs to be replaced by a new one, i.e. a need to establish urgently ‘a new common sense’, which could rise as a ‘postgrowth, decolonial, ecofeminist … and postcapitalist imaginary’ (Prádanos Reference Prádanos2018, 15). This is done by overpowering the current schizophrenic injunction of ‘sustainable development’ as an economic form of ‘colonialism in disguise’ (Escobar et al. Reference Escobar, Kothari, Salleh, Demaria and Acosta2019) which generates a malaise and a global existential crisis (Daly Reference Daly, Daly and Townsend1993, 267–268). This new imaginary, starting with a decolonization of our everyday vocabulary (see D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis Reference D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015; as well as Le Guin Reference Le Guin1974; and Damasio Reference Damasio2020), could then give rise to a new human society by creating the conditions necessary for its emergence.

Degrowth as political activism – or, in the end, how to ‘re-enchant’ (Latouche Reference Latouche2019a) a ‘disenchanted world’? (Weber Reference Weber2003, 83). As underscored by Latouche (2019a), despite obvious signs of weakness after the financial crisis of 2008, the neo-liberal order has a strong ability to maintain things as they are and to disrupt any kind of potential evolution coming from activist movements (Latouche Reference Latouche2019a, 109). It was once believed that the re-enchanting of the world would pass through the grand soir (i.e. the ‘revolution’, as the necessary myth of the working-class movement to support its development). However, nowadays a revolution can only occur through the advent of a wave of mass ‘economic atheism’, a dis/de-belief in growth and competition, a renouncement of the ritual of consumptions, and a global agnosticism about progress (Latouche Reference Latouche2019a, 113). This decolonization of our minds, expectedly judged as unrealistic by many, would nonetheless constitute the prerequisite to a construction of a new society based on conviviality, autonomy and frugality, and resulting in a form of sustainable no-growth society. This would be established not as a religion or a cult, but rather as a philosophy, a ‘wisdom’ (from French sagesse, in Latouche Reference Latouche2019a, 114). It is thus a bet on the maturity of our contemporaries, and on our abilities, first, to expose the failure of our macro-economic structures leading the capitalist oligarchy to be disarmed and neutralised (Latouche Reference Latouche, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015b, 95; see also Piketty Reference Piketty2019, illustrating that inequalities are an ideological choice, not a fatality), and, second, to foresee and implement other ways of living and other sets of values (Latouche Reference Latouche2019a, 120).

To do so, propositions and attempts to implement an agenda have been formulated in different forms, from which a sequence can be used as a simple schematic basis for our reflection: (1) anti-growth, (2) alter-growth, (3) degrowth and (4) no-growth. This sequence is not restricted to a succession of steps in a linear fashion. The initial three steps suggested here can be implemented simultaneously and/or in various orders, aiming, in the end, to establish a no-growth society.

The general failure of archaeology in the neo-liberal economy, namely salvage/commercial archaeology, and cultural-heritage management (CRM)

Through the concomitant processes of colonization and globalization … local or ‘traditional’ heritage stewardship strategies were – and continue to be – extinguished, replaced by capitalist heritage regimes focused on large- or industrial-scale resource extraction, production, and consumption

Hutchings (Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 71, quoting Bodley and Ross).

During the last decade, I dedicated most of my research efforts trying to deconstruct the mechanisms which affect archaeological practices within the neo-liberal system around the globe (Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin Reference Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin2019; Zorzin 2011a; Reference Zorzin2013; Reference Zorzin, Gnecco and Lippert2015a; Reference Zorzin2015b; Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b; Reference Zorzin2017). Many others tackled critically the situation of archaeology and cultural heritage (Parga-Dans Reference Parga-Dans2019; Hutchings Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018; Aparicio Resco Reference Aparicio Resco2016; Hutchings and La Salle, 2015; Reference Hutchings and La Salle2013; Kehoe Reference Kehoe, Hamilakis and Duke2007; Hamilakis and Duke Reference Hamilakis and Duke2007; Hamilakis Reference Hamilakis1999; Reference Hamilakis2015; Shanks and McGuire Reference Shanks and McGuire1996). All these analyses pointed out a major and problematic shift faced by archaeologists during the 1980s and 1990s, with major consequences today: a global reform of archaeological practice toward a commercial form, privatized, competitive and profit-oriented, making the discipline market-compatible, and so ‘adapted’ to the new neo-liberalized environment, as defined previously by Stiegler (Reference Stiegler2019a; Reference Stiegler2019b).

Even though few within the archaeological community would phrase it this way, the discipline was then made complicit in neo-liberal doctrinal standards (Hutchings Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 83), which happened increasingly fast in academia (Wurst Reference Wurst2019, 169). It took place with the consent of most archaeologists who, legitimately (as Canadian archaeologists confided to me in 2008; see Zorzin Reference Zorzin2011b, 249–687), wanted to ‘live with their time’, and ‘to find the best way to deal with this unchallengeable reality’ which, it should be remembered, occurred in a period of fast increase of wealth, despite cyclical crises (Guay Reference Guay2019).

As was emphasized by Yannis Hamilakis in Reference Hamilakis1999, that new relationship might have constituted the initial ‘betrayal’ of archaeologists to the intrinsically intellectual and social natures of their work. Yet, reflecting on the neo-liberalization process, and considering neo-liberalism as an insidious and hidden ideological colonizer, it would be misplaced to accuse archaeologists of deliberate betrayal, as most of them are not aware of what exactly they were getting into. Archaeologists could certainly not have foreseen the consequences of the reforms, mostly consisting of the privatization of their activities, which was, as stated by my interviewees around the world, the most ‘natural’, ‘logical’, ‘common-sense’ way to do archaeology at the time (Zorzin Reference Zorzin2011b). It was indeed a time of great opportunities for an increasing number of people to become professional archaeologists, free from state or academic limitations. For a short period, privatization was a truly liberating, self-empowering and intellectually stimulating change for many archaeologists. In the long run, however, it was a misleading choice.

Furthermore, it should be clarified again that in a post-1980s context, no clear distinction can be made between the work environment of ‘commercial’, ‘state’ and ‘academic’ archaeologists (see Gil Reference Gil, Flood and Gill2009; Wurst Reference Wurst2019), because they are all working in the same neo-liberal framework, made equally cost-efficient at many different levels by the institutions they are working for (Zorzin Reference Zorzin2016a). Nonetheless, another clarification is important here, even though endlessly repeated through the years (Hutchings and La Salle Reference Hutchings and La Salle2013, 1–3; Zorzin Reference Zorzin2015b, 792–793; Reference Zorzin2011a, 120–121; Reference Zorzin2010); critiques of the values of institutions are by no mean personal critiques. Even though ‘commercial archaeology’ is now dominant or mainstream, it should not be absolved of critique or responsibilities. Unfortunately, this distinction and the subsequent necessary detachment needed from everyday practice seem a challenge for many (Hutchings and La Salle Reference Hutchings and La Salle2013, 2–3).

For at least two to four decades after implementation, the new neo-liberal governing paradigm ended up ‘fetishizing’ (Hamilakis Reference Hamilakis, Hamilakis and Duke2007, 23) and ‘commodifying’ (McGuire Reference McGuire, Hamilakis and Duke2007, 10) the archaeological discipline as a technical tool (Hutchings Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 82). Through this it was largely emptied of its original scientific research-oriented goals, erasing its social connection through professionalization and nullifying archaeologists’ working traditions of living willingly on the margin of capitalist society (Everill Reference Everill2009, 83–103). It furthermore degraded the working conditions of archaeologists, as well as the traditions of solidarity within the working community (Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin Reference Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin2019, 110).

All in all, it comes back to two fundamental questions. First, for whom are we doing archaeology? Remembering the fact that archaeology is not only about science and techniques, but mostly about domination of political power (McGuire Reference McGuire, Hamilakis and Duke2007, 10). Second, for what future are we doing archaeology? Stating firmly that only a ‘shift … towards the making and shaping of collective futures … will build capacities for archaeology and heritage to be more effectively connected with the social, economic, political and ecological challenges of our time as their future solutions’ (Högberg et al. Reference Högberg, Holtorf, May and Wollentz2018, 645). Recently, Hutchings (Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 80–81) has emphasized the fact that neo-liberalism has been successfully implemented in archaeology and that most archaeologists now prefer to ‘play by the rules of the game’, despite severe warnings (Aparicio Resco Reference Aparicio Resco2016; Hamilakis and Duke Reference Hamilakis and Duke2007; Hamilakis Reference Hamilakis1999; Shanks and McGuire Reference Shanks and McGuire1996). Hutchings (Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 80–81) explained this dominant tendency towards a ‘sustained optimism’, ‘resourcism’ or extractivism as a neutral approach, uncritical and/or unaware of the doctrine it is embedded into. In order to survive, ‘optimism’ based on exploitation of limited resources has to rely heavily on concepts such as ‘sustainable development’, perfectly ‘adapted’ to the neo-liberal authoritarian strategy of pretending to fight climate change, environmental degradation and destruction of cultural heritage, but in fact willingly ignoring them (i.e. green-washing destructive policies). Yet ‘to ignore or forget is to externalize capitalism’s gruesome toll on natural and cultural heritage’ (Hutchings and La Salle Reference Hutchings and La Salle2013, 1). Whether living in neo-liberal democracies or autocracies, this is the situation that we are experiencing now: archaeology is de facto deeply embedded in the neo-liberal logic (Zorzin Reference Zorzin, Gnecco and Lippert2015a; Reference Zorzin2015b).

How can degrowth contribute to entering a new paradigm in archaeology? Some illustrations from France and Canada

I suggest that the response to the existential crisis provoked by the logic of growth must be a radical one. As Hutchings (Reference Hutchings, Stiefel and Wells2018, 81) defined it, it is through a ‘deconstructivist postmodernist’ approach that archaeologists can take a stance against the utopic and self-destructive logic of growth and make a socio-ecological commitment towards populations and cultural-heritage preservation, as a collaborationist attitude towards development and competition is no longer viable.

As a matter of fact, if archaeological or cultural-heritage sites are considered and defined as ‘resources’, their exploitation, displacement or destruction will be regarded as acceptable or as a lesser evil than slowing down economic development. Furthermore, a resource is expected to be exploited and depleted at some point, which is entirely oxymoronic for archaeologists and cultural-heritage managers who are supposed to be working for the preservation of the human past.

As an answer to that situation, the degrowth set of ideas could help archaeology to challenge the toxic software which has become the currently dominant commercial/contract-managed archaeology almost everywhere on the planet. As such, I would like to assemble some propositions for the future practice of an archaeology as a radical degrowth actor.

Degrowth as ‘civil disobedience’ (Thoreau Reference Thoreau2017) Civil disobedience represents a first possible action which can support the degrowth movement, simply by opposing the structural violence of the neo-liberal order (Louis Reference Louis2014). Today, the concept is often used in the context of global ecological struggles, aiming at shifting some cultural norms to discourage unsustainable levels of consumption. It is also current in some political/humanitarian activism, for example concerning occupation and the use of native populations’ lands, the mistreatment and abuse of minorities or refugees. However, it is also used, for instance, against utilitarian laws that encourage the commodification of the commons, which sometimes causes structural oppression of certain classes of people.

This approach might seem obstructive through its appearance as a blunt and unethical agenda, but civil disobedience tends to be much more effective and sturdier (in relatively functional democracies) when it is associated with propositions of constructive alternatives (Renou Reference Renou, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 164). As such, a development project, or even a research project, causes various issues for the archaeologists involved: ethical questions on identities, memories, ownership, colonization, methodological problems, etc. In certain cases, it creates an intolerable dissonance for the archaeologists who try to accomplish their tasks but are forced (by both financial and time pressures, weak or nonexistent enforcement of legal protections, and quality standards defined by ticking boxes) to create a low-quality ‘product’, irrelevant and invisible for most.

In situations of this type, and especially if they are recurrent, the only way to preserve moral integrity and personal and professional dignity, and to avoid depression or painful self-denial, is to act. Actions can take many different forms, from collective resistance to orders (i.e. not doing as instructed – see Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b, 320–321), to unionization (see Unite Archaeology, for example, in Ireland since 2014), to active sabotage. The strength of an action of civil disobedience is proportional to the numbers of actors involved and its duration (Ott Reference Ott2019, 41). For example, ‘sabotage’ (which can be simply translated as the implementation of an ‘archaeological work ethic’ in an alienated archaeological context) can be achieved by quietly increasing the excavation’s standards, resulting in inflating the time needed to accomplish the task properly, or simply by taking the time to talk to the public. The latter two actions will certainly result in the paradoxical accusation from developers of archaeologists being provocatively ‘unprofessional’, while archaeologists are precisely trying to be respectful of the minimum ethical standards. Here, even though archaeologists are involved in a non-violent collective action they will certainly trigger different forms of repression (see Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b), which will amplify the importance of the initial revendication (Ott Reference Ott2019, 41).

All these actions can potentially result in not getting future contracts, closing archaeological services, and even potential bankruptcy, but this, as we mentioned previously, is the unfortunate prerequisite to a refoundation. Yet if national laws continue to protect heritage (or if it becomes a community requirement in a post-capitalist system), the work and expertise of archaeologists will always be needed; not, however, in the form it previously existed. It is up to archaeologists to continue supporting the destruction of heritage for the interest of developers (corporate or state-controlled) or to refuse to play this role any longer and return frontally to political contestation, something that is unavoidable while dealing with archaeology and cultural heritage.

For archaeologists, instead of accepting being increasingly used as the architects of a sacralized process of not slowing down development, I would rather, in conformity with the slow and reflexive nature of the scientific method implemented in archaeology and the absolute necessity of its public involvement, again become so-called ‘growth objectors’ (from the French objecteurs de croissance – Mongeau Reference Mongeau2007).

A radical opposition like this will automatically be joined with taking risks and with putting the entire professional archaeology community as we know it in danger. Yet this drastic turn could be the opportunity for a return to a pre-1980s situation (in a French context), i.e. with archaeologists being activists, often willingly fighting back against what they see as useless mega-infrastructure projects, and involved in sociopolitical conflicts (Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin Reference Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin2019, 110). During that period, most French fieldwork archaeologists were operating without the security of a permanent job, and without regular incomes, even though many French archaeologists at the time could continue their archaeo-activist actions while receiving different forms of state unemployment or low-income financial support. Yet as the emancipation of workers/archaeologists cannot be achieved without the minimum means to sustain both professional activities and a decent life, I would propose to counterbalance the major issues created by potential income losses or income insecurity by implementing degrowth as a redistribution process (see the third point below), precisely to avoid precarity and its deleterious effects.

At this point in the contribution, an important clarification needs to be made to contextualize this radical proposal of resisting or sabotaging neo-liberal management that can put archaeologists–workers in precarious positions. It would be legitimate to ask here how such an approach can be suggested, while not discussing its potential consequences. In fact, the impetus behind my reflection is based on first-hand experience as a field technician (on and off during the last twenty years, at the same time as being a precarious scholar). A large part of the ideas developed in this article emerged from some relatively successful attempts at joint group opposition in a specific archaeological mega-project in 2015 (See Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b, 312–321).

Since then, having directly experienced precarity, poverty, bleak living conditions and degraded health, and having had to deal with a massive student debt, a conclusion was reached within our group of field archaeologists: to renounce archaeology as a job and find another source of income, preferably more socially significant. We also came to an agreement that we could only go back to archaeology if it could be more meaningful (even with a modest income), and if we could regain full control of the fieldwork’s aims, methodologies, interpretations and communication. Our working community mostly perceived commercial archaeology as an alienating practice, and as alienated by developers’ managerial methods. At that time, it was impossible for any of us to see how commercial archaeology could fulfil our shared aspirations apart from the fact of earning an income (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 161). As such, it was necessary to urgently distance ourselves from commodified archaeology and look for alternatives (see also Hamilakis Reference Hamilakis2015).

Degrowth as voluntary simplicity

[Voluntary simplicity is] a way of life that involves consciously minimizing wasteful and resource-intensive consumption. But it is also about reimagining ‘the good life’ by directing progressively more time and energy toward pursuing non-materialistic sources of satisfaction and meaning.

Alexander (Reference Alexander, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 133)

Voluntary simplicity is indeed at the core of the disruption process of the neo-liberal order, through encouraging a cultural transition toward restrained consumption, ideally willingly implemented by people (but most probably by the absence of a choice because of recession or collapse). This transition will only be viable if a critical mass of individuals accepts the fact that wealth and material accumulation cannot be the basis for a fulfilled life, and that this accumulation is, in fact, toxic at the individual and the global level. In contrast, voluntary simplicity advocates seeking accomplishment in a life based on community and social engagement, equity between people, solidarity, fulfilling employment, intellectual and artistic projects, craftsmanship, political involvement and pleasure seeking (Stan Reference Stan and Mongeau2007, 93). Following this logic, a resistance process could lead archaeologists to an exile from private and state structures (as suggested previously) regulated by the logic of the competitive market, to a reformation into independent structures (such as NPOs, cooperatives) or into amateur-based/citizen-controlled (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 162) structures (associations, small municipalities).

For example, in the case of the current French semi-state-based archaeological system, this radical solution could be avoided if salvage archaeology could return to 2001’s law situation, with an archaeology entirely protected from the competitive market economy. Yet, in the current dominant neo-liberal political framework this is a far-fetched perspective, and even more problematic considering that the state structure (Institut national de recherches archéologiques préventives – INRAP) for archaeology’s ‘polluter–payer’ financial base still relies on growth and therefore cannot escape the competitive economic logic which comes with it (Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin Reference Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin2019, 110–111).

However, considering the current situation in France, with almost no economic growth at a national level since 2008, the legal framework of 2003 opening archaeology to a competitive market accommodated the potential disappearance of archaeological structures if proven economically incompatible with or not ‘adapted’ (see Stiegler Reference Stiegler2019a; Reference Stiegler2019b) to the current free-market logic. This is already occurring in France, through bankruptcy of some private operators, but also through the downsizing or dismantling of archaeological services within local authorities (collectivité teritoriales), and through the slow death of INRAP, universities and research centres. This occurred predominantly through non-renewed departures for retirement, budget cuts, decreasing employment, precariousness and low salaries. In the short term, and in an unchanged neo-liberal framework, the most probable scenario for French archaeology is a collapse of the public sector, but a survival of few major private operators within an increasingly deregulated configuration, like the UK system (see Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b; Shepperson Reference Shepperson2017). In the end, these might potentially be absorbed by major engineering or by infrastructure corporations serving only their own legal interests (Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b, 314).

This downfall scenario, however, could theoretically result in the creation of a new form of cooperative organizational structure for archaeology, or a reactivation of the old amateur network, which used to thrive in France before the 1970s. These new independent establishments could then provide a new framework to practise archaeology, placing autonomy and fulfilment at the centre of their craft. This means the pleasure of accomplishing a complex and meaningful task, the satisfaction of producing results, and the gratification of social interactions involving knowledge sharing, conviviality and solidarity. When the obligation of profit is eradicated, monetary needs would be limited to supporting a decent life for archaeologists and their families – nothing less, nothing more.

Additionally, we should note that the concept of ‘voluntary simplicity’ can also be applied directly to archaeological fieldwork. As such, the concept can challenge our excavation methodologies, which currently still emphasize the questionable extensive and expensive process of artefact and data accumulation. Against this accumulation process, a minimalist approach combining a large panel of non-destructive operations could be implemented: underground non-invasive detection combined with digital recording technologies, targeted small trenches and a zero-waste policy could also considerably change the look of our still mostly extractivist activities. This should come with a simultaneous redirecting of our practices and aims toward community involvement, such as that suggested by Flexner (Reference Flexner2020, 166) involving a ‘slow-science’ model in which open discussion and ‘storytelling’ take precedence over the accumulation of data.

Degrowth as a redistribution process In a society of degrowth, work aims at satisfying the needs of the community instead of the urges of material possession. A degrowth economy is, then, an opportunity to exchange goods and services on a small scale and an occasion to contribute to community life according to one’s skills and knowledge (Mongeau Reference Mongeau2007, 134).

In term of redefining work and economy, a few different directions have to be explored: first, ‘defining basic and maximum income’ (Alexander Reference Alexander, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 146–148) i.e. providing enough income for people to have a decent and dignified life but less income for luxury consumption; second, a ‘job guarantee’ (Unti Reference Unti, Murray and Forstater2018, 63), i.e. a decentralized program relying on local governments, non-profits, and community organizations; and third, work sharing (Schor Reference Schor, D’Alisa and Kallis2015, 195–197), meaning better-distributed job opportunities and working toward flexible working-hour norms, moving from 40 hours per week (five to six days) to 20–25 hours per week (approximately three days). This will avoid unemployment for many in a context of high labour productivity (notably due to mechanization and digitalization), and nevertheless will significantly reduce the annual carbon footprint and increase spare time for social and political activities (Schor Reference Schor, D’Alisa and Kallis2015, 196). The main idea behind these propositions is to give workers an opportunity to maintain their independence (intellectual and physical) through the security of a basic income and/or through the guarantee of a job, and through limitations in monetary gains and in working hours/days, allowing them to avoid bank debts and dependence on an employer.

In the current climate, archaeologists implying the aforementioned disobedience and voluntary simplicity on a daily basis would be sanctioned or sacked. The solutions to thwart the loss of jobs and incomes organized in a capitalist fashion would be to provide a ‘job guarantee’. This would work at the level of communities and NPOs and would consist of implementing archaeological programmes according to local (even modest) means and needs (such as free accommodation; free and fast Internet access; providing equipment, health coverage and free education for kids, for example). As such, archaeologists would eradicate their current financial precarity and permanent internal competition to get contracts within the free-market economy. Although they might lose in geographical stability, this type of employment requiring a certain mobility through time can prove to be truly meaningful for long-term community-based projects. In such a configuration, archaeologists would have to prioritize the needs of the community over their research and personal interests (see Le Guin Reference Le Guin1974).

In fact, such an experimental configuration has already occurred. It happened without any ‘degrowth’ theoretical framework involved, but as an organic and intuitive development. In Quebec (Canada), an NPO called Archéo-08 has existed since 1985 as the result of an encounter between the citizens of a region, who expressed their desire to develop archaeological research, and an archaeologist, the late Marc Côté. Côté took up the challenge of a more independent archaeological project by moving to a remote area of Quebec with his family and essentially relying financially on the local community for material support, and on regional and national subventions (the Ministry of Culture and Communications, notably). The project was far from perfect, or financially stable, and involved a constant struggle to receive the financial means to support a long-term endeavour (according to dialogue established with Côté in 2008). One of the most astounding characteristics of the NPO was that it was populated by enthusiastic archaeologists who were proud of the results of their research and the quality of interactions with the local population. Even though embedded in an archaeologically competitive provincial system, the geographical distance of the NPO from urban centres (where the archaeological companies are based) played a buffer role, allowing its existence to be based in a different politico-economic form from the capitalistic one, and this continues to be so today.

The idea of a national/regional ‘basic minimum income’ (BMI), as the provision of identical payments from a government (national, regional or local) to all citizens to meet a person’s or a family’s basic needs, could empower labour over capital and ‘strengthen the power of civil society to shape the priorities for the use of the social surplus and the organization of economic activity’ (Wright Reference Wright2005, 2). This is particularly relevant to archaeology where a BMI could not only guarantee that archaeologists proceed to their most visible work – the digging – but guarantee that they do analyses, research, publications and, most importantly, community-based involvement in the long term as well. The absence of means and time for these essential activities in market competitive archaeology is one of the main explanations for its loss of direction in recent decades (Högberg et al. Reference Högberg, Holtorf, May and Wollentz2018, 642–644; Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin Reference Vandevelde-Rougale and Zorzin2019, 111). By providing a BMI, based on a non-competitive, non-profitable, co-constructed project within a community, an archaeologist or a team of archaeologists can plan, at least for some years, to establish themselves successfully as decommodified workers, and moreover as happy ones.

However, this said, a pattern that has emerged recently illustrates the ability of neo-liberalism to digest almost any form of ideological innovation initially hostile to it, and then produce a perverted version of the original defiant proposal. A corrupted BMI would then consist of stimulating constant consumption (aiming only to avoid recession and degrowth), as a new neo-liberal avatar coming to the rescue of the capitalist logic. In contrast to this, the BMI imagined/suggested in this article is seen as a truly redistributive system, which can only be foreseen at a small scale (a settlement, a city state, an eco-community) from which work can no longer be used to control and extract wealth from oppressed workers. Rather, it works ‘to free people to pursue the kind of work they find interesting and fulfilling’ (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 162). Yet in my view a BMI should function as a transitional process during the distancing from the capitalist system until work becomes an instrument of proper emancipation at the service of a small-scale community who have chosen a ‘subsistence-oriented way of life’. After this, a BMI should no longer be necessary. As Illich (Reference Illich1980, 52) notes,

There, the inversion of development, the replacement of consumer goods by personal action, of industrial tools by convivial tools is the goal. There, both wage-labor and shadow-work will decline since their product, goods or services, is valued primarily as a means for ever inventive activities, rather than as an end, that is, dutiful consumption. There, the guitar is valued over the record, the library over the schoolroom, the back-yard garden over the supermarket selection. There, the personal control of each worker over his means of production determines the small horizon of each enterprise, a horizon which is a necessary condition for social production and the unfolding of each worker’s individuality.

No growth as a sustainable society

For the term ‘sustainability’ to finally gain meaning (again), it needs to be decolonized urgently, i.e. extracted from its oxymoronic meaning given by the neo-liberal dogma as an achievable and desirable goal conciliating economic growth and life sustainability on Earth (Jarrige Reference Jarrige2016, 5; Sauvé Reference Sauvé and Mongeau2007; and cf. the concept of ‘green capitalism’ mentioned earlier). ‘Sustainable growth’ needs to be recognized as a toxic concept serving two main purposes: first, justifying corporations’, states’ or individuals’ unethical and unsustainable social and environmental actions which aim solely at short-term profits, and second, luring the masses into believing that they can redeem themselves from overconsumption with so-called responsible behaviour, while in fact maintaining the same self-destructive habits.

In contrast, it is within the informal economic strategies of small (eco-)communities, with small-scale farming and artisan work, that a form of ‘economic localism’ can take place to sustain a no-growth society:

the change in relations of production in terms of creating self-sufficient or even self-reliant communities … would be geared exclusively by the choice to cover the basic needs of all citizens and those of the non-basic needs that citizens themselves decide to cover collectively, through their democratic assemblies and individually, through a voucher scheme and an artificial ‘market’ (Fotopoulos Reference Fotopoulos2007, 14).

To define and manage the primary and secondary needs of a community, the concept of ‘commons’ can be of assistance (Parance and Saint Victor, Reference Parance and de Saint Victor2014). ‘The commons are usually understood in two primary senses: as 1) a paradigm of governance and resource-management, and 2) as a set of social practices in virtually all fields of human endeavour’ (Helfrich and Bollier Reference Helfrich, Bollier, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 75; see also Bollier Reference Bollier2014; Euler Reference Euler2018, 1–18). It is easier to use the term as a verb: ‘commoning’, which defines all the processes of shared stewardship about things that a group benefits from and manages in common. The most important aspect of ‘commoning’ is its ability to regain ownership and control over the means of production, as well as its social commitment, the networking and the exchange of knowledge it involves in the management of a specific resource, being either nutritional, natural, territorial or cultural. The key in a successful management of commons would then be to clearly define what it is that we (the archaeologists and the communities concerned) would like to regain control over, and ‘what is to be shared and how’ (Helfrich and Bollier Reference Helfrich, Bollier, D’Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015, 76).

However, downscaling human life to small communities and restabilizing ‘commons’ will not be enough, and, as suggested by Latouche (Reference Latouche2019a, 119–123), a step further in the establishment of a no-growth society is required, notably through ‘re-enchanting’ our lives. Would this consist of creating new mythologies, new religious dogma? This is not the purpose or the intention; rather, re-enchanting is simply to give a space for people to dream once again and retake the necessary mental space for transcending reality.

As such, what ‘degrowth’ thinkers argue for is aiming to see the realities of the world from different perspectives, delivering new meanings, and creating new ways of thinking and new ways of doing, outside the neo-liberal matrix, and outside the disenchantment, apathy and smallness of our fully commodified lives. As such, poetry, aesthetics, art, music and potentially archaeology can today be the means to make us rediscover the sense of wonder of our childhood, as well as purpose and fulfilment.

Because the existence of archaeology has been progressively indexed on the level of urban development and infrastructural development, our social relevance cannot be taken in consideration any more, or only after demonstrating the financial viability of archaeology in the free-market economy. This viability has proved untenable in a competitive configuration. Our ‘production’ remains unwanted by the dominant neo-liberal ideology, because, so far, archaeologists still represent a potential disruption of progress for developers and local governments, unless an archaeological site or a heritage site’s preservation, or accidental destruction (cf. Notre-Dame de Paris burning in 2019), can serve electoral goals, gentrification, nationalist views or benefactors’ interests (e.g. tax deductions). Moreover, a new strategy has been developed by numerous developers to commodify further an unwanted archaeology, by turning it into a ‘green-washing’ product with a very positive impact for the image of the company (see Zorzin Reference Zorzin and Aparicio Resco2016b, 323–324), exploiting the concepts of both ‘social responsibility’ and ‘sustainable development’, while being mostly socially and ecologically irresponsible.

In a degrowth economy, the concept of ‘sustainability’ could regain its full meaning, and archaeology could find its place within autonomous cooperatives, NPOs and associations, existing in close coordination with the aspirations of communities, by which these structures are partially or totally supported (as we saw above).

The existence of archaeology would then depend on the communities’ consensus, consisting in defining archaeology as a non-basic need which is, nevertheless, an essential need to be covered for the well-being of the community, notably by establishing a ‘sense of community and sense of place’ through a ‘convivial activity’ (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 163). It could become a pivotal and symbolic way of commoning.

Local citizens would therefore participate actively in defining how control could be reclaimed over heritage. This will be done in collaboration with archaeologists who would need to compromise in better integrating social demands and present needs about understanding and discussing the past in their agenda, as is already the case in community-based archaeology experiments around the globe (Atalay Reference Atalay2019, Moshenska Reference Moshenska2017, Matsuda and Okamura Reference Matsuda and Okamura2011). However, community-based archaeology, also called ‘public archaeology’ (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 164), is not necessarily absolved from neo-liberal, neo-colonial and self-serving agendas, or from being ‘instrumentalized’ and making irreversible damage to communities (Pudney Reference Pudney, Williams, Pudney and Ezzeldin2019, 121). Indeed, it has often been disappointing to witness some public-archaeology projects becoming ‘an orthodoxy within the social sciences reproducing the culture of silence around archaeology’s pivotal role in the ongoing disempowerment of Indigenous peoples, their heritage, and their land’ (La Salle and Hutchings Reference La Salle and Hutchings2016, 174, citing Menzies; see also Zorzin Reference Zorzin2014).

As such, the future survival of a dissident, convivial, anti-capitalistic, non-self-serving archaeology will also depend on our ability to make it socially relevant. I believe that this will only be possible by letting go of the current technically fetishized, monetarized and politically neutralized archaeological practices to finally establish a ‘craft archaeology’: ‘a socially engaged practice which is not alienating’ (Shanks and McGuire Reference Shanks and McGuire1996, 76). I suggest that this could happen with the essential help of creative expression and the artistic display of archaeological processes and results, aiming at a radical re-enchanting, as well as a radical critique, of neo-liberalism, and a decolonization of our dystopian consumerist realities.

I intend to experiment and explore further the possibilities offered by the association of artistic performances and archaeology, notably in Japan, and hopefully in Greece in collaboration with artists, performers, film directors and digital technologies. In this I am aiming at co-constructing (or ‘co-producing’; see Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 164) new imaginaries for the present, for the past, for ourselves, for others, with others, and for the pleasure of sharing this with the community’s members. Artists and archaeologists both have a pivotal role to play in the process of bridging the past and articulating it somehow in the present. Yet the fact that this type of archaeology is necessarily ephemeral, incidental, organic, unique to its context and fundamentally collaborative (Flexner Reference Flexner2020, 165) makes it largely impossible to provide a descriptive prospect of what a performative archaeology in degrowth could or should look like.

Concluding discussion: towards an insubordinate, post-capitalist future for archaeology?

In the first part of this article, we saw that the neo-liberal imperative to ‘adapt’ to the acceleration of the commodification of all aspects of our lives successfully colonized most of humanity and established a cultural hegemony (Gramsci Reference Gramsci1971). Yet the neo-liberal agenda has proved to be self-destructive ecologically through the injunction of growth, and socially harmful through the imperative of competition. It was then suggested that a movement called ‘degrowth’ could help structure resistance against this dogma. Instead of maintaining the status quo and despite the reluctance of many to face the unsustainable economic configuration we are living in, the degrowth movement suggests pushing towards another acceleration. The latter would aim for the ending of the current capitalist system and for the re-establishment of human interactions centred on a set of values such as social justice, empowerment, dignity, solidarity and collaboration, grounded in a set of possible common actions. Finally, we saw that archaeology was equally colonized by a competitive market-oriented mentality, even though archaeology has always been deeply implicated in the capitalist structures since its beginnings (particularly within colonial processes), and even though it is now paradoxically largely populated by a community actively seeking non-alienated work (Zorzin Reference Zorzin2016a). In this part, some responses to the objectification of archaeology were presented, and confronted with some concepts aggregated within the degrowth movements: civil disobedience, voluntary simplicity and redistribution of means (and/or reappropriation of the means of production). Through some concrete examples, we explored how to prepare to transition towards a no-growth society, within which the current form of archaeological practices could no longer exist.

While we are constantly reminded that we have to adapt to the new reality, because we no longer have any other choice, and while we live in a time when ‘reforms’ are supposed to be compulsory, beneficial and urgent, few dare to name the nature of these changes which have affected archaeology since the 1970s, always presented as ‘apolitical’ and pure ‘common sense’. The reality of archaeology is that it has been largely made compatible with the neo-liberal agenda: efficient, profitable, with a primacy for competition and economic growth.

Thus accepting the transitioning of archaeology away from its commercial practice could come with the advent of an archaeology of degrowth. Such a post-capitalist archaeology could reconnect with communities and engage itself in facing the current and future global fears of humanity concerning pandemic, industrial disasters (such as the proposed Fukushima project – see Schlanger, Nespoulous and Demoule Reference Schlanger, Nespoulous and Demoule2016), pollution, economic recession, overexploitation, neo-colonialism and environmental and financial collapse.

As suggested by Antonio Gramsci in his Prison notebooks (1971), it is only by preparing the masses’ imaginaries to be free from capitalist (now neo-liberal) cultural hegemony and its ‘manufacturing of consent’ that we will be able to act and establish a new horizon for humanity based on notions of commons, collective duties and collective consciousness of society.

What could archaeology do or be to participate into this ongoing conflict of imaginaries, now dominated by neo-liberal values? From my perspective, degrowth-driven archaeology can do its part by being a field of experimentation for our own post-capitalist emancipation, but most importantly for the emancipation of the communities we are interacting with. Through a degrowth experimental and non-dogmatic approach, we could give ourselves the means to mutate.

  • By repositioning our activities in the sphere of politics as an ‘anti-growth’ activity, defending the primacy of common interests against abusive economic forces (corporate development or neo-liberal authoritarian states). Archaeologists, through civil disobedience, could regain dignity by acting collectively, accordingly to shared work ethics, and regain a sense of purpose by taking over the means of production, the cost of which would probably be the loss of our commercialized jobs, and our predominantly developer-based incomes.

  • To continue to exist and play any kind of constructive role in communities, archaeologists could then regroup in non-profit cooperatives, which could be supported, through redistribution, by different means. This could be achieved by community-based concrete material support and completed or fully supported by a ‘basic minimum income’. This would not be indexed on quantitative standards, but on the qualitative results (despite the difficulties of evaluating these – see Pudney Reference Pudney, Williams, Pudney and Ezzeldin2019, 110) of decommodified labour, embedded in communities, until the latter decides collegially that the collaboration should end.

  • Without direct financial exchange between actors in a non-profitable, ‘no-growth’-based economy, archaeology would thus justify and sustain its existence uniquely from the fact that it participates actively in the the social life of the communities who have chosen to make archaeology and cultural heritage a significant common.

  • Finally, a post-capitalist archaeology might have to be implemented through new forms of display and dissemination, notably by using artistic and radical expressions openly critical of the capitalist order (if it still prevails), and/or openly aiming to ‘re-enchant’ the present.

At the time of writing this discussion, the COVID-19 pandemic is challenging the very existence of the present capitalist global configuration. Yet both neo-liberal states and corporations are fighting back with all their strength to save, as expected, not people, but the capitalist economic structure. It is still uncertain what consequences the coronavirus outbreak will have in the future, but whether the ‘free-market economy’ collapses or not, this is again (similar to the 2008 speculative/financial crisis) the time for us to engage in provocative changes. What the current crisis calls for is indeed a reimplementation of solidarity, with humanité at the centre of everything, in opposition to the failing neo-liberal economic system and its individualist, self-centred ideology. It is time to reorganize the role of the state and its public services, and if archaeology cannot be part of it without succumbing to free-market competition and being systematically undermined (as is the case in France today), the renaissance will have to occur outside the state. This will inevitably come with a major destabilization of the ‘industry’ before it mutates in a potential new and more modest, degrowth- or community-based configuration, free from the inherent competitive mentality imposed by neo-liberalism as the main characteristic of human interactions. To reiterate, that mutation would mean accepting that we will lose our jobs. I personally made peace with that prospect long ago and accepted its potential professional and personal consequences. Until things change, I will continue to challenge colleagues and students, by actively discussing the true nature of our current archaeological practices and proposing that together we continue exploring inventive alternatives.

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank all the scholars who agreed to participate in this contribution by further opening the debate about the degrowth movement, and helped me to clarify further my own arguments through their pertinent comments and positively challenging questions; the Fondation maison des sciences de l’homme (FMSH) for its financial support through the Fernand Braudel–IFER Post-doctoral Fellowship COFUND, and the UMR 8215 trajectoires and its members, which helped in conducting fieldwork in France and the United Kingdom, and contributed greatly to the current reflection; and the patient and kind proofreaders Dr Lucy Watson and Dr Sophie Violet Moore.

References

Alexander, S., 2015: Simplicity, in D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 146148.Google Scholar
Altman, D., 2005: Neoliberalism? It doesn’t exist, New York Times, 16 July 2005, available at www.nytimes.com/2005/07/16/business/worldbusiness/neoliberalism-it-doesnt-exist.html.Google Scholar
Aparicio Resco, P. (ed.), 2016: Archaeology and neoliberalism, Madrid.Google Scholar
Atalay, S., 2019: Can archaeology help decolonize the way institutions think? How community-based research is transforming the archaeology training toolbox and helping to transform institutions, Archaeologies. Journal of the World Archaeological Congress 15(3), 514535.Google Scholar
Bailey, R., 2018: Is degrowth the only way to save the world? Welcome to the latest gussied up version of Malthusian eco-pessimism!, Reason, 16 February 2018, at https://reason.com/2018/02/16/is-degrowth-the-only-way-to-save-the-wor.Google Scholar
Bollier, D., 2014: La renaissance des communs. Pour une société de coopération et de partage, Paris.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, P., 1998: L’essence du néoliberalisme. Cette utopie, en voie de réalisation, d’une exploitation sans limite, Le monde diplomatique, March 1998, 3.Google Scholar
Cervera-Marzal, M., 2016: Les nouveaux désobéissants. Citoyens ou hors-la-loi?, Lormont.Google Scholar
Chomsky, N., 2013: Le bien commun. Entretien avec David Barsamian, Montréal.Google Scholar
D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), 2015: Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London.Google Scholar
Daly, H.E., 1993: Sustainable growth. An impossibility theorem, in Daly, H.E. and Townsend, K.N. (eds), Valuing the Earth. Economics, ecology, ethics, Cambridge and London, 267273.Google Scholar
Damasio, A. (ed.), 2020: Le réveil des imaginaires, Socialter, hors-série.Google Scholar
Demaria, F., Schneider, F., Sekulova, F. and Martinez-Alier, J., 2013: What is degrowth? From an activist slogan to a social movement, Environmental values 22, 191215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escobar, A., Kothari, A., Salleh, A., Demaria, F. and Acosta, A., 2019: ‘Development’ is colonialism in disguise. Others worlds are possible – the pluriverse is breathing, Open Democracy, at www.opendemocracy.net/en/oureconomy/development-colonialism-disguise/?fbclid=IwAR3Ade152MDSCyjBRofIGoXcXGlPvLzhqgRVeGxrnF0148BWrgFZKlpdK2c.Google Scholar
Euler, J., 2018: The commons. A social form that allows for degrowth and sustainability, Capitalism nature socialism 30(2), 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Everill, P., 2009: The invisible diggers. A study of British commercial archaeology, Oxford and Exeter (Heritage Research Series 1).Google Scholar
Faubert, D., 2019: ‘Eco-anxiety’. How to spot it and what to do about it, BBC three news, 27 March 2019, at www.bbc.co.uk/bbcthree/article/b2e7ee32-ad28-4ec4-89aa-a8b8c98f95a5.Google Scholar
Flexner, J. 2020: Degrowth and a sustainable future for archaeology, Archaeological dialogues 27, 159171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fotopoulos, T., 2007: Is degrowth compatible with a market economy?, International journal of inclusive democracy 3(1), 116.Google Scholar
Gil, R., 2009: Breaking the silence. The hidden injuries of neo-liberal academia, in Flood, R. and Gill, R. (eds), Secrecy and silence in the research process. Feminist reflections, London, 228244.Google Scholar
Gorz, A., 1980: Ecology as politics, Montréal.Google Scholar
Gramsci, A., 1971 (1929–1935): Selections from the prison notebooks of Antonio Gramsci, New York.Google Scholar
Guay, J.-H., 2019: Perspective monde. Outil pédagogique des grandes tendances mondiales depuis 1945, Ecole de politique appliquée (Faculté des lettres et science humaines, Université de Sherbrooke, Québec, Canada, at http://perspective.usherbrooke.ca/bilan/servlet/BMTendanceStatPays?codeTheme=2andcodeStat=NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZGandcodePays=FRAandoptionsPeriodes=peReEcoandcodeTheme2=2andcodeStat2=NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZGandcodePays2=USAandoptionsDetPeriodes=avecNomPandlangue=fr.Google Scholar
Hale, S.M., 1990: Controversies in sociology, Toronto.Google Scholar
Hall, S., and O’Shea, A., 2013: Common-sense neoliberalism. The battle over common sense is a central part of our political life, Soundings 55, 824.Google Scholar
Hamilakis, Y., 1999: La trahison des archéologues. Archaeological practice as intellectual activity in postmodernity, Journal of Mediterranean archaeology 12(1), 6079.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilakis, Y., 2007: From ethics to politics, in Hamilakis, Y. and Duke, P. (eds), Archaeology and capitalism. From ethics to politics, Walnut Creek, 1540.Google Scholar
Hamilakis, Y., 2015: Archaeology and the logic of capital. Pulling the emergency brake, International journal of historical archaeology 19 (4), 721735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilakis, Y., and Duke, P. (eds), 2007: Archaeology and capitalism. From ethics to politics, Walnut Creek.Google Scholar
Harvey, D., 2005: A brief history of neoliberalism, Oxford.Google Scholar
Harvey, D., 2016: Neoliberalism is a political project. An interview with David Harvey conducted by Bjarke Skaerlund Risager, Jacobin, 23 July 2016, at www.jacobinmag.com/2016/07/david-harvey-neoliberalism-capitalism-labor-crisis-resistance.Google Scholar
Harvey, D., 2017: Marx, capital and the madness of economic reason, London.Google Scholar
Helfrich, S., and Bollier, D., 2015: Commons, in D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 7578.Google Scholar
Högberg, A., Holtorf, C., May, S. and Wollentz, G., 2018: No future in archaeological heritage management?, World archaeology 49 (5), 639647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hutchings, R.M., 2018: Meeting the shadow. Resource management and the McDonaldization of heritage stewardship, in Stiefel, B.L. and Wells, J.C., Human-centered built environment heritage preservation. Theory and evidence-based practice, Abingdon, 6787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hutchings, R.M., and La Salle, M., 2013: Five thoughts on commercial archaeology, ICHT Bulletin 2013-1, at https://criticalheritagetourism.files.wordpress.com/2015/08/icht-bulletin-2013-1.pdf.Google Scholar
Hutchings, R.M., and La Salle, M., 2015: Archaeology as disaster capitalism, International journal of historical archaeology 19(4), 699720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Illich, I., 1980: Vernacular values, Philosophica 26, 47102.Google Scholar
Jackson, T., 2017: Prospérité sans croissance. Les fondations pour l’économie de demain, 2nd edn, Louvain-la-Neuve.Google Scholar
Jarrige, F., 2016: Les précurseurs de la décroissance. Gravelle, Zisly et les anarchistes naturiens contre la civilisation industrielle, Neuvy-en-Champagne.Google Scholar
Kallis, G., Demari, F., and D’Alisa, G., 2015: Degrowth, in D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 117.Google Scholar
Kallis, G. and March, H., 2014: Imagineries of hope. The utopianism of degrowth, Annals of the Association of American Geographers 105(2), 360368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kehoe, A.B., 2007: Archaeology within marketing capitalism, in Hamilakis, Y. and Duke, P. (eds), Archaeology and capitalism. From ethics to politics, Walnut Creek, 169178.Google Scholar
Kempf, H., 2009: Pour sauver la planète, sortez du capitalisme, Paris.Google Scholar
La Salle, M., and Hutchings, R., 2016: What makes us squirm. A critical assessment of community-oriented archaeology, Canadian journal of archaeology/Journal canadien d’archéologie 40, 164180.Google Scholar
Latouche, S., 2004: Survivre au développement. De la décolonisation de l’imaginaire économique à la construction d’une société alternative, Paris.Google Scholar
Latouche, S., 2015a: Decolonization of imaginary, in D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 117120.Google Scholar
Latouche, S., 2019a: Comment réenchanter le monde. La décroissance et le sacré, Paris.Google Scholar
Latouche, S., 2019b: La décroissance, Paris.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Latouche, S., and Jappe, A., 2015: Pour en finir avec l’économie. Décroissance et critique de la valeur, Paris.Google Scholar
Le Guin, U.K., 1974: The dispossessed, New York.Google Scholar
Lopez, G., 2017: Cornel West’s attacks on Tanehisi Coates, explained, Vox, 20 December 2017, at www.vox.com/identities/2017/12/20/16795746/ta-nehisi-coates-cornel-west-twitter.Google Scholar
Louis, E. (ed.), 2014: Pierre Bourdieu, l’insoumission en héritage. Ce que la vie fait à la politique, Paris.Google Scholar
Lydon, C., 2017: Noam Chomsky. Neoliberalism is destroying our democracy. How elites on both sides of the political spectrum have undermined our social, political, and environmental commons (interview, 1 June 2017), The Nation, at www.thenation.com/article/noam-chomsky-neoliberalism-destroying-democracy.Google Scholar
McGuire, R.H., 2007: Politics is a dirty word, but then archaeology is a dirty business, in Hamilakis, Y. and Duke, P. (eds), Archaeology and capitalism. From ethics to politics, Walnut Creek, 910.Google Scholar
Matsuda, A., and Okamura, K. (eds), 2011: New perspectives in global public archaeology, New York, Heidelberg and London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P., 2014: The political movement that dared not speak its own name. The neoliberal thought collective under erasure, Institute for News Economic Thinking, Working Paper 23, September 2014.Google Scholar
Mirowski, P., 2018: Neoliberalism. The movement that dare not speak its name, American affairs 2(1), 118141.Google Scholar
Moshenska, G. (ed.), 2017: Key concepts in public archaeology, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mongeau, S. (ed.), 2007: Objecteurs de croissance. Pour sortir de l’impasse: la décroissance, Montréal.Google Scholar
Moore, J.W., 2017: World accumulation and planetary life, or, why capitalism will not survive until the ‘last tree is cut’, Progressive review 24(3), 175202.Google Scholar
Ott, H., 2019: Petit Manuel de désobéissance civile. Restons dans l’action, Yggdrasil 1, Effondrement et renouveau, 38–43.Google Scholar
Parance, B., and de Saint Victor, J. (eds.), 2014: Repenser les biens communs, Paris.Google Scholar
Parga-Dans, E., 2019: Heritage in danger. The collapse of commercial archaeology in Spain, Archaeological dialogues 26, 111122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pethokoukis, J., 2017: Who needs progress anyway? Not the ‘degrowth’ movement, AEIdeas, 27 March 2017, at www.aei.org/publication/who-needs-progress-anyway-not-the-degrowth-movement.Google Scholar
Piketty, T., 2019: Capital et idéologie, Paris.Google Scholar
Prádanos, L.I., 2018: Postgrowth imaginaries. New ecologies and counterhegemonic culture in post-2008 Spain, Liverpool.Google Scholar
Pinker, S., 2018: Enlightenment now. The case for science, reason, humanism and progress, New York.Google Scholar
Pudney, C., 2019: Instrumentalised archaeology. Cease and desist?, in Williams, H., Pudney, C. and Ezzeldin, A. (eds), Public archaeology. Arts of engagement, Oxford, 109125.Google Scholar
Radio Open Source (Arts, ideas, and politics with Christopher Lydon), 2017: Welcome to our neoliberal world, 16 March 2017, Boston.Google Scholar
Redclift, M., 2005: Sustainable development (1987–2005). An oxymoron comes of age, Sustainable development 13(4), special issue, Critical perspectives on sustainable development, 212227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Renou, X., 2015: Disobedience, in D’Alisa, G., Demaria, F. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 162164.Google Scholar
Sauvé, L., 2007: La dérive et l’impasse du développement durable, in Mongeau, S. (ed.), Objecteurs de croissance. Pour sortir de l’impasse: la décroissance, Montréal, 3357.Google Scholar
Schlanger, N., Nespoulous, L. and Demoule, J., 2016: Year 5 at Fukushima. A ‘disaster-led’ archaeology of the contemporary future, Antiquity 90 (350), 409–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartzman, D., 2012: A critique of degrowth and its politics, Capitalism nature socialism 23(1), 119125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Servigne, P., and Stevens, R., 2015: Comment tout peut s’effondrer. Petit manuel de collapsologie à l’usage des générations présentes, Paris.Google Scholar
Shanks, M., and McGuire, R.H., 1996: The craft of archaeology, American antiquity 61(1), 7588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sizaire, V., 2019: Des sans-culottes aux ‘gilets jaunes’, histoire d’une surenchère répressive. Maintien de l’ordre, les faux-semblants du modèle français, Le monde diplomatique, April 2019, 4–5.Google Scholar
Stan, D., 2007: De l’individuel au collectif. Stratégies de changement: La simplicité volontaire, in Mongeau, S. (ed.), Objecteurs de croissance. Pour sortir de l’impasse: La décroissance, Montréal, 9296.Google Scholar
Stiegler, B., 2019a: ‘Il faut s’adapter’. Sur un nouvel impératif politique, Paris.Google Scholar
Stiegler, B., 2019b: ‘S’adapter. Le nouvel horizon du libéralisme?’, La grande table des idées, France Culture, Paris, 26 January 2019, radio broadcast, at www.franceculture.fr/emissions/la-grande-table-2eme-partie/sadapter-le-nouvel-horizon-du-liberalisme.Google Scholar
Spratt, D., and Dunlop, I., 2019: Existential climate-related security risk. A scenario approach, breakthrough, Melbourne.Google Scholar
Swift, R., 2014: S.O.S. Alternatives to capitalism, Oxford.Google Scholar
Tanuro, D., 2013: Green capitalism. Why it can’t work, London.Google Scholar
Thoreau, H.D., 2017 (1849): La désobéissance civile (first published as Civil disobedience), Paris.Google Scholar
Vandevelde-Rougale, A., and Zorzin, N., 2019: De la professionnalisation à la vassalisation. L’archéologue, entre éthique professionnelle et responsabilité sociale d’entreprise, Canadian journal of bioethics/Revue canadienne de bioéthique 2(3), 109119.Google Scholar
Waterton, E., and Smith, L. (eds), 2009: Taking archaeology out of heritage, Newcastle upon Tyne.Google Scholar
Weber, M., 2003 (1917): Le savant et le politique, tr. Catherine Colliot-Thélène, Paris.Google Scholar
Weiss, M., and Cattaneo, C., 2017: Degrowth. Taking stock and reviewing an emerging academic paradigm, Ecological economics 137, 220230.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wright, E.O., 2005: Basic income as a socialist project, paper presented at the annual US-BIG Congress, 4–6 March 2005 (University of Wisconsin), at www.ssc.wisc.edu/˜wright/Basic%20Income%20as%20a%20Socialist%20Project.pdf.Google Scholar
Wurst, L.-A., 2019: Should archaeology have a future?, Journal of contemporary archaeology 6(1), 168181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2010: Archéologie au Québec. Portrait d’une profession, Archéologiques 23, 115.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2011a: Contextualising contract archaeology in Quebec. Political-economy and economic dependencies, Archaeological review from Cambridge 26 (1), 119135.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2011b: The political economy of a commercial archaeology. A Quebec case-study, doctoral thesis, Faculty of Humanities, University of Southampton, at https://eprints.soton.ac.uk/344777.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2013: The political economy of Japanese archaeology. Reflective thoughts on current organisational dynamics, Japanese journal of archaeology 1, 117.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2014: Heritage management and Aboriginal people. Relations in a global economy. The contemporary challenges of Victoria (Australia), Archaeologies 10(2), 132167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2015a: Archaeology and capitalism. Successful relationship or economic and ethical alienation?, in Gnecco, C. and Lippert, D. (eds), Ethics and archaeological praxis, New York and London (World Archaeological Congress (WAC) 1) 115139.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2015b: ‘Dystopian archaeologies. The implementation of the logic of capital in heritage management, in C. Gnecco and A. Dias (eds), Disentangling contract archaeology, special issue of International journal of historical archaeology 19(4), 791–809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2016a: Economie et philosophie politique de l’archéologie préventive française. Naissance, institutionnalisation et in-corporation d’un commun, Les nouvelles de l’archéologie 146, 5559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2016b: New managerial strategies in British commercial archaeology, in Aparicio Resco, P. (ed.), Archaeology and neoliberalism, Madrid, 297325.Google Scholar
Zorzin, N., 2017: Archaeology and development in Taiwan. The case of Hanben, AP. Journal in public archaeology 7, 2132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brick, H., 2014: Fortune-tellers of the capitalist world, Journal of American studies 48(3), 873878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, J., 2014: Across the great divide. Free markets from right to left, Modern Intellectual History 11(1), 253265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peck, J., 2013: Explaining (with) neoliberalism, Territory, politics, governance 1(2), 132157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schor, J.B., 2015: Work sharing, in D’Alisa, G. and Kallis, G. (eds), Degrowth. A vocabulary for a new era, New York and London, 195198.Google Scholar
Unti, B.J., 2018: The job guarantee and transformational degrowth, in Murray, M. and Forstater, M. (eds), Full employment and social justice, Cham (Binzagr Institute for Sustainable Prosperity), 6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar