Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T00:11:01.102Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Indigenous Nations and the Development of the U.S. Economy: Land, Resources, and Dispossession

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 March 2022

Ann M. Carlos*
Affiliation:
Professor, Department of Economics, University of Colorado Boulder, CO 80309.
Donna L. Feir
Affiliation:
Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of Victoria, Victoria, BC, Canada, V8P 5C2, Center for Indian Country Development, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, and IZA Institute for Labor Economics, University of Bonn. E-mail: dfeir@uvic.ca.
Angela Redish
Affiliation:
Professor, Vancouver School of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, BC Canada, V6T 1L4. E-mail: angela.redish@ubc.ca.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Abundant land and strong property rights are conventionally viewed as key factors underpinning U.S. economic development success. This view relies on the “Pristine Myth” of an empty undeveloped land, but the abundant land of North America was already made productive and was the recognized territory of sovereign Indigenous Nations. We demonstrate that the development of strong property rights for European/American settlers was mirrored by the attenuation and increasing disregard of Indigenous property rights. We argue that the dearth of discussion of the dispossession of Indigenous nations results in a misunderstanding of some of the core themes of U.S. economic history.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Economic History Association

A standard account of the growth and development of the United States describes an evolution from struggling European settlements to the world’s most successful economy.Footnote 1 This depiction focuses on the roles of access to abundant land, technological adaptation, migration, enhanced human capital, and “governments that established private property rights, rules of law and protections of individual freedom,” with many seeing land and natural resources at the core of nineteenth- and twentieth-century growth.Footnote 2 Yet the standard emphasis on abundant land, property rights, the rule of law, and protection of individual freedom erases the narrative of the millions of people present when European ships arrived—people whose productive activities had already shaped the land, cultivated its natural resources, and whose own institutions of property and governance managed intra- and inter-nation relationships (Denevan Reference Denevan1992; Mann Reference Mann2005).

In this paper, we provide a framework and chronology for understanding and teaching American economic history, describing how land came to be owned by European settlers and their descendants in large measure by undermining Indigenous relationships to their property.Footnote 3 We chart the path by which Indigenous peoples in the contiguous United States were transformed from the sovereign owners of the land to economically impoverished participants in U.S. economic growth: Peoples who went from being the tallest in the world (Steckel and Prince Reference Steckel and Prince2001) with among the highest standards of living (Carlos and Lewis Reference Carlos and Lewis2010b) to some of the lowest per capita income groups in the United States with some of the lowest life expectancies (Akee and Taylor Reference Akee and Taylor2014; U.S. Commission on Civil Rights 2018). When the experiences of Indigenous nations are included, the sweeping narrative of the United States as a leader in the security of property rights and rule of law, and hence its economic success (Sokoloff and Engerman Reference Sokoloff and Engerman2000; Cain, Fishback, and Rhode Reference Cain, Fishback and Rhode2018), must be questioned or at least amended.Footnote 4

Land and institutions are deeply intertwined, not least through the construction of borders that define ownership and legal jurisdiction. Institutions—political, economic, and social—and resource abundance, are not exogenously determined but are socially constructed (Wright Reference Wright1996). Political institutions set the rules determining who votes, who makes the laws, and who decides on resource allocations, all of which, in turn, influence courts, common law, commercial law, and property rights (North Reference North1991; North, Wallis, and Weingast Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009). In North America, these forces have led to high incomes and wealth for many but have left others in poverty.Footnote 5

In 1840, Alexis de Tocqueville wrote that “in no other country in the world is the love of property keener or more alert than in the United States, and nowhere else does the majority display less inclination towards doctrines which in any way threaten the way property is owned.”Footnote 6 Here we focus on the ways by which property came to be owned and by whom, and most importantly, how the land came into the public domain of the United States.Footnote 7 The United States was never an empty land waiting for European farmers—the “Pristine Myth” is a demonstrable fallacy. The land was wholly owned by Indigenous nations who would be dispossessed both within and outside the rule of law.

The history of this transfer of resources from Indigenous nations to settlers is ignored in much of the economic history literature.Footnote 8 Our goal is to spur its inclusion in the core narratives of U.S. economic growth. First, the paper addresses the frame within which much of this economic history is written, that of settlers or colonial/state/federal governments. The disregard of Indigenous agency renders Indigenous peoples invisible in both the broad themes and, more specifically, in the context of rights to land. Some recent papers on that topic either never mention Indigenous people or use Indigenous land merely as an instrument or as a robustness check.Footnote 9 Models that claim to understand or predict the evolution of property rights, wealth, or economic development, while simultaneously ignoring Indigenous proprietors of the land, distort history.

Second, we argue that although it is often claimed that the United States established legal ownership through rights of conquest or through the purchase of lands from other colonial powers (Allen Reference Allen2019, p. 260) or that “the land was not held by recognized parties” (Libecap Reference Libecap, Louis, Price and Paul2018, p. 5 ), none of these statements are correct. The government of the early Republic recognized the sovereign power of Indigenous nations. However, over the course of the nineteenth century, the courts, Congress, the Office of the President, and the use of the military changed the rules of the game to enhance settler access to land and resources in the face of previously recognized Indigenous claims. Third, we make a conceptual contribution by explicitly discussing how sovereignty and individual property rights interact, and the connection to de jure laws and de facto norms in the context of Indigenous nations and the federal government.Footnote 10

We bring together decade-by-decade data on land cessions, treaties (ratified and unratified), reservation land, and data on population densities to chronicle the pattern of land transfer from Indigenous nations. We use these data to provide evidence that the acquisition of Indigenous land not only changed the boundaries of the United States but that even low levels of settlement of adjacent areas accelerated the transfer of land. When combined with evidence of worsening treaty terms for Indigenous nations, this suggests that increases in the threat point of the United States progressively eroded the ability of Indigenous nations to maintain sovereign jurisdiction over the land.

This paper complements the emerging literature on Indigenous economic history, which focuses heavily on the Dawes Era (1887–1934) but is largely separate from that on the development of the American economy.Footnote 11 Papers in this literature focus on natural resource loss (Feir, Gillezeau, and Jones Reference Feir, Gillezeau and Jones2019), forced co-existence of different Indigenous nations on reservations (Dippel Reference Dippel2014), the extent of federal oversight on reservations (Frye and Parker Reference Frye and Parker2021), and residential schools (Gregg Reference Gregg2018). Each had major consequences for Indigenous economic growth but would have been impossible without the political, legal, and economic changes before 1871, which are the main focus here.

We first present the conceptual framework used to structure our discussion, distinguishing between the concepts of sovereignty and property. We then address two misconceptions: The Pristine Myth and the belief (in U.S. economic history) that Indigenous peoples and nations were not recognized parties in American law. Next, we focus on the forces that diminished the relative bargaining power of Indigenous nations vis-à-vis the federal government—the legal system, squatting, immigration, railways, and violence—providing descriptive and empirical evidence. Finally, we summarize the implications of this paper for understanding the dispossession of Indigenous nations and U.S. economic growth.

CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

The transfer of land from Indigenous peoples to settlers involved the loss of two distinct sets of rights: land ownership and sovereignty. We discuss the distinction between the two and how these concepts relate to “good institutions” and the rule of law.

Property and Sovereignty

Title or ownership of land has been described as a bundle of “Blackstonian” rights: the right to use or alter, to exclude, and to transfer elements to others (Ellickson Reference Ellickson1993).Footnote 12 Fee simple ownership, sometimes called “complete” property rights, means that the owner has full and irrevocable ownership of the land and/or buildings. Distinct from fee simple ownership, occupation or possession of land could refer to socially recognized possession such as rental or leasing, or unlawful occupation such as squatting.

Blackstonian rights over land can be allocated to individuals or a collective. The strength of any given property right can be measured by the probability the right is enforced (Alchian Reference Alchian, Eatwell, Milgate and Newman1991). As Demsetz (Reference Demsetz1967, p. 347) wrote: “Property rights are an instrument of society and derive their significance from the fact that they help a man form those expectations which he can reasonably hold in his dealings with others. These expectations find expression in the laws, customs, and mores of a society.” The key point is that property rights are socially constructed and enforced. Individuals can say they have a right to something and attempt to enforce it, but such actions will be costly or ineffective in the absence of a collective that agrees with them.

We define sovereignty as the ability to specify and enforce laws that govern a specific geographic space, including regulating who and what may cross the territorial borders.Footnote 13 The laws specified and enforced by sovereigns relate to property and criminal and civil laws. As such, transfers of sovereignty convey not merely land but also the authority to specify rights and enforce the “rules of the game.” In contrast, transfers of individual property rights, whether it be full fee simple rights or only use rights, do not imply a legal or sovereign regime change. If a Canadian buys a house and title to the underlying land in the United States, Canada does not acquire sovereign jurisdiction over the house nor the ability to enforce Canadian law on that land; nor would a Canadian assume that this was the transaction implied. When two members of different sovereignties transfer land rights, it might have a marginal impact on the effective sovereignty of both. However, if too many such transactions occur it can destabilize the existing institutions, that is, they may cause “sovereignty spillovers”—the effect of individuals’ transactions on the ability of the sovereign to enforce its laws within its jurisdiction.

Limiting negotiations over property to the inter-sovereign domain can mitigate spillovers. Sovereign-to-sovereign land transfers resolve uncertainty over whose laws apply when a property transaction occurs because those transactions move the border of each sovereign’s jurisdiction. Treaties between Indigenous nations and the United States government are the written records of sovereign transactions over land that occurred between mutually recognized nations. Such negotiations do not fully eliminate possible sovereignty externalities because a sovereign may choose laws that can have implications for another collective’s effective sovereignty (Dennison Reference Dennison2017). Additionally, changes in territorial size may lead to increasing demands for more land, while, conversely, a decrease in territory puts pressure on a society and its social norms, potentially resulting in a breakdown in the ability to enforce norms and to a splintering of the collective. Treaty making had consequences on both sides of the border but also changed the balance of power for nations beyond those that signed the documents.

Good Institutions

Property rights, institutions, and growth are intertwined. Sokoloff and Engerman (Reference Sokoloff and Engerman2000) argued that differences in the long-term development of the United States relative to the West Indies reflected the impact of differences in the initial distribution of land ownership (family farm vs. plantation) on political structures. Similarly, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, Aghion and Steven2005, p. 395) define good economic institutions as those “that provide security of property rights and relatively equal access to economic resources to a broad cross-section of society” and that put “constraints on the actions of elites, politicians, and other powerful groups, so that these people cannot expropriate the incomes and investments of others or create a highly uneven playing field” (Acemoglu Reference Acemoglu2003, p. 27). Thus “good institutions” have two dimensions—security of property rights and constraints on expropriation (Lamoreaux Reference Lamoreaux2011).

Normally discussed in the context of a given sovereign jurisdiction, we consider these dimensions as they relate to sovereign-to-sovereign transactions. We follow Banner (Reference Banner2005) in noting that there was no sharp distinction between voluntary and involuntary transactions in U.S.- Indigenous treaty-making, but rather transactions lay on a spectrum that extended from mutually beneficial and free exchange to outright theft. Thus “good institutions” would be those negotiated and enforced to maintain a level playing field and provide a foundation for future investment. The terms of a contract reflect the relative bargaining power of the parties, and for parties whose outside options diminish, the terms of the contract typically worsen. In a world of “good institutions,” however, once a contract is signed, further changes in a party’s position would not lead to forced renegotiation.Footnote 14

ADDRESSING THE PRISTINE MYTH: NOT AN EMPTY LAND

The depiction of North America as an empty land barely affected by human presence has been called the Pristine Myth (Denevan Reference Denevan1992). Despite substantial and compelling evidence to the contrary, it continues to persist, explicitly or implicitly, in economic history narratives. To take just one recent example, De Zwart and van Zanden (Reference De Zwart and van Zanden2018, p. 90) write of “the native Americas (sic) succumbing en masse to European violence and diseases” and the area “repopulated by Europeans, Africans, and later Asians.” North America was not an empty land when the Europeans arrived, nor did Indigenous people disappear with the arrival of Europeans.Footnote 15 Ethnographers have mapped the territories of Indigenous nations around 1600 (see Figure 1). The map must be understood as a snapshot, with national boundaries of Indigenous nations shifting and changing and with use-rights overlapping during certain periods for certain nations (Dunbar-Ortiz Reference Dunbar-Ortiz2014). What the map makes clear is just how many different Indigenous nations comprised the “Indian” population, and that while population density was unevenly distributed throughout the continent, reflecting the distribution of natural resources, the entire continent was claimed as the sovereign territory of at least one nation.

Figure 1 THE SPATIAL DISTRIBUTION OF INDIGENOUS NATIONS 1600

Source: Martin and O’Leary (1990).

Twentieth-century estimates of the population at the time of contact— for North America north of urban Mexico to the Arctic—range from 1.2 to 18 million.Footnote 16 These estimates are based largely on contemporary accounts from European observers or environmental carrying capacity. More recent estimates, using the spatial distribution of archaeological remains in the eastern half of North America, reduced the upper end of the range to 6.1 million (Milner and Chaplin Reference Milner and Chaplin2010, p. 708).

The Americas prior to contact were not empty of people, nor was it an environment free of disease or violence. In a multidisciplinary study of 12,520 skeletal remains distributed over 64 sites in the Americas—from as early as 6000 bce to the middle of the eighteenth century, Steckel and Rose (Reference Steckel and Rose2002, table 1.1) create a health index to measure the wellbeing of different groups at different points in time. Over half of the sample, 6,472 skeletal remains, come from sites in North America, and of these, about half are from sites dated to before contact. One result is notable. Computed from the earliest skeletal remains, Indigenous societies were progressively less healthy prior to contact: as in Europe, greater urbanization and settled agriculture had negative health consequences.

Table 1 IMPORTANT U.S. LAND LEGISLATION

Sources: Information in this table has been compiled from Allen (Reference Allen1991), Atack and Passell (Reference Atack and Passell1994), and Rohrbough (Reference Rohrbough1990).

Land across North America had already been heavily affected by human processes and modified to meet peoples’ economic needs well before the arrival of Europeans.Footnote 17 Some impacts were obvious: “Earthworks, roads, fields, and settlements were ubiquitous” (Denevan Reference Denevan1992, p. 369) and large-scale agriculture was practiced by numerous societies. Ancestors of the Pimas (Hohokam) in what is now Arizona built one of the most extensive networks of irrigation canals in the world. One Pima canal system carried enough water to irrigate an estimated ten thousand acres of land (Mann Reference Mann2005). The Haudenosaunee (Iroquois) had large-scale agriculture: a French traveler in 1669 reported six square miles of cornfields surrounding each Haudenosaunee village; 20 years later, the Governor of New France reported that he had destroyed more than a million bushels of corn from two Haudenosaunee villages (Dunbar-Ortiz Reference Dunbar-Ortiz2014). At the same time, many of the ways Indigenous people shaped the environment might not have been recognized as such by Europeans. Forest landscapes had been modified through burning to create havens for game and space for gardens. Indigenous people also cultivated bison herds by using fire to extend the short-blade grasslands beyond their natural range (Isenberg Reference Isenberg2000; Mann Reference Mann2005; Dunbar-Ortiz Reference Dunbar-Ortiz2014; Zedeño, Ballenger, and Murray Reference Zedeño, Ballenger and Murray2014).

Surpluses from Indigenous production were traded across the continent through a vast system of trading networks (Dunbar-Ortiz Reference Dunbar-Ortiz2014). This trade was facilitated by numerous commodity currencies, some of which were adopted by European colonists (Taxay Reference Taxay1970). Lutz (Reference Lutz2009) argues that the trading jargon, Chinook, used with British and French traders, pre-dated contact and had facilitated trade among the linguistically diverse nations from Alaska to California.

Territoriality was understood by Indigenous nations, as were the boundaries that defined a nation’s lands. Shared rights were well defined, and when ignored, war or violence could result. At the same time, migrations from environmental change or predator-prey cycles did occur and changed boundaries between Indigenous communities (Ray Reference Ray1974). Within a nation, property could be held privately or as limited-access common property or communally. In some nations, land was held by families stretching over generations, while in others, it was reallocated more often (Carlos and Lewis Reference Carlos and Lewis2010a). Migratory big game such as bison, caribou, or deer were held as common property (Carlos and Lewis Reference Carlos and Lewis2010a; Benson Reference Benson, Terry, Bruce and Thomas2006), while fishing rights, beaver ponds, weapons, or jewelry were personal, family, or private property (Anderson 1992; Lutz Reference Lutz2009) with sharing and redistribution standard as ways to mitigate the risk of starvation or to attenuate competition/violence over resource sites (Johnsen Reference Johnsen1986). In sum, property rights across the continent were diverse and varied but clearly present.

Indigenous polities’ authority structures were equally diverse: confederacies, house-structures, leagues, chieftainships, or extended kin-based groupings—matrilinear and patrilinear (Borrows and Coyle Reference Borrows and Coyle2017). Unlike in Europe, positions of political authority or hierarchy were often appointed or elected through tribe-specific mechanisms rather than inherited. Although the power structure appeared diffuse to Europeans, it was well defined within nations. After contact, family control over particular plots of land or the lack of a clear hierarchy caused problems, especially in relation to the authority to sell/transfer land to others—specifically when that transfer may have implications for sovereign jurisdiction.

INDIGENOUS SOVEREIGNTY TO 1800

When English settlers arrived in Jamestown in 1607, the philosophy that Europeans owned the land due to a “right of discovery” or religion (as Christians) was waning in European legal and popular thinking. Nonetheless, colonists came to the Americas with promises of land from colonial companies.Footnote 18 The reality was that the land was neither free nor unsettled and, by the mid-eighteenth century, even settlers accepted that Indian nations owned the land and held jurisdiction over land they had not sold (Banner Reference Banner2005).

Transfer of sovereignty or jurisdiction in lands sold to individuals or colonies, through formal treaties or less formal agreements to purchase, created a gray area. Were individual colonists who purchased land from an Indigenous nation essentially settling in the Indigenous nation (as when Canadians buy land in the United States), or was the plot transferred to the sovereignty of the European power? To the extent that colonists were leasing land, as they sometimes did, they were moving to Indigenous territory, but if the contract was intended as a sale, many assumed that the land became colonial territory. Although contracts to lease and to buy are conceptually different, in reality, either side could argue that one or the other was intended. To reduce legal wrangling or conflict, Indigenous nations, colonies, and the Crown moved to a position allowing only nation-to-nation transactions of purchase—as in the Royal Proclamation of 1763.Footnote 19

The Proclamation was the (intended as temporary) response of the British crown to land issues after the 1763 Treaty of Paris. Under the Treaty, the French Crown ceded its rights to lands west of the Allegheny Mountains (some of which colonies claimed under their charter rights)— plus land held in what is known today as Canada—while maintaining their rights over the Louisiana territory. Settlers in the 13 colonies had anticipated opening this land for colonial settlement (indeed, some colonists believed that their charter gave them rights to the land), but the Royal Proclamation declared it Indigenous territory.Footnote 20 Although the Proclamation changed only which European power had the right to treat with Indigenous nations, some colonists perceived it as land theft. For Indigenous nations, the removal of French influence changed the balance of power between them and the Crown, and subsequently, the federal government.Footnote 21 Finally, and crucially for our discussion here, because it would be the model for subsequent federal legislation, the Royal Proclamation declared that only the Crown (or his/her representatives) could purchase Indigenous territory and that that purchase must occur at a public meeting within the Indigenous nation. The Crown, thus, became a monopsonist in the purchase of Indigenous land. While the Royal Proclamation of 1763 was a unilateral declaration, in 1764, chiefs from 24 nations across North America signed the Treaty of Niagara, agreeing to nation-to-nation land sales only (Redish Reference Redish2019).

After the American Revolution, transfers of land between Indigenous nations and the United States continued to take place at the level of the sovereign power, which, per the Constitution, was the federal government. The Non-Intercourse Act of 1790 declared: “no purchase, grant, lease or other conveyance of lands, or of any title or claim thereto, from any Indian nation or tribe of Indians, shall be valid, unless the same be made and duly executed by some public treaty held under the authority of the United States.”Footnote 22 Neither the Proclamation nor the Non-Intercourse Act stopped individual settlers from trying to buy land from Indigenous people, but that land would not have legal title and could not be registered or used as collateral (Priest Reference Priest2021).

The new Republic, thus, recognized Indigenous nations as sovereign. While consistent with English legal tradition, it was also expedient. For a federal government with little by way of fiscal resources, lacking a standing army, and fearing invasion from Canada, bargaining power lay with Indigenous nations. The federal government saw Indigenous nations both as potential allies and as potential foes who could align with other European powers. Furthermore, the new nation saw land as a solution to its daunting fiscal woes. Land was an asset, and land sales a possible source of revenue, while conflict over land was a potential expense. By 1790 the federal government had concluded that purchasing land rights was cheaper than seizing land. Indigenous nations arguably had superior military power and technology (and the capacity to use it), and their military capacity posed a serious threat to those attempting to seize their land.Footnote 23 In 1792, Thomas Jefferson wrote to David Campbell (Judge in the Southwest Territory): “I hope too that your admonitions against encroachments on the Indian lands will have a beneficial effect - the U.S. finds an Indian war too serious a thing to risk incurring one merely to gratify a few intruders with settlements which are to cost the other inhabitants of the U.S. a thousand times their value in taxes for carrying on the war they produce. I am satisfied it will ever be preferred to send armed force and make war against the intruders as being more just and less expensive” (cited in Prucha Reference Prucha1962, p. 139).

Yet, even as the new Republic accepted Indigenous sovereignty, it was laying the framework for how land could become a new territory or state within the Union. The 1785 Land Ordinance laid out how land would enter the public domain and move from the public domain into private hands—purchased land would be surveyed in a rectangular grid and sold at public auction with minimum prices and quantities defined by Congress. The Northwest Ordinance of 1787 detailed how a territory would be incorporated into the political system. The operation of the Land Ordinance and the Northwest Ordinance put pressure on relations with Indigenous nations, which shifted the balance of power and the strength of de jure law as it applied to interactions with Indigenous nations.

EVOLVING U.S. INSTITUTIONS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR INDIGENOUS NATIONS

The land area of the United States has grown beyond its 1783 borders. Often, it is assumed that the public domain increased with the Louisiana Purchase (1803), the Florida Acquisition (1819), the Texas Annexation (1845), the Oregon Country (1846), the Mexican Acquisition (1848), the Gadsden Purchase (1853), the Alaska Purchase (1867), and the annexation of Hawaii (1898). Indeed, American economic history texts often show the territorial expansion of the Republic demarcated by these acquisitions, as in Figure 2. The most recent Historical Statistics of the United States (Carter et al. Reference Carter, Gartner, Haines, Olmstead, Sutch and Wright2006, table Cf1 3-345) gives acreage in the public domain as the land area of these intra-European transfers. Not only is this incorrect, but it also distorts reality. What was acquired by the United States was not land but rather an exclusive right to treat with the sovereign Indigenous nations whose land lay within these boundaries. The expansion of the Republic is captured rather by treaties conducted with individual Indian nations; treaties with Indigenous nations were required to bring land into the public domain.Footnote 24 Transfers of Indigenous sovereign territory, shown in Figure 3, delineate land transfers by decade and thus more closely represent the actual territorial expansion of the United States.Footnote 25

Figure 2 UNITED STATES ACQUISITION OF NEGOTIATION RIGHTS

Notes: This map should be understood as U.S. acquisition of monopoly rights to treat with Indigenous nations. See, for example, Figures 9.1 Atack and Passell (Reference Atack and Passell1994); Map 8.1 Walton and Rockoff (2013); Figure 5.3 Hughes and Cain (2010).

Source: National Geographic: Territorial Gains by the U.S. Maps of landed gained by the U.S. Accessed from https://www.nationalgeographic.org/photo/territorial-gains/, 26 February 2021.

Figure 3 LAND CESSION TREATIES TO 1871 (BY DECADE)

Notes: Treaty transfers in dark; reservations depicted in light shade; eastern regions not included in Royce data; the 18 hidden treaties in in California depicted in a somewhat darker—see text. Use rights could be negotiated as a condition of transfer.

Source: Bureau of American Ethnology in 1899 under the guidance of Charles C. Royce, digitized by Saunt (Reference Saunt2014).

The expansion of U.S. territory reflected the conjuncture of changes in the legal recognition of Indigenous sovereignty and the decline in the (relative) bargaining position of Indigenous nations. We unpack this process by documenting the challenge of delineating borderlands, describing how the Marshall court changed the legal landscape, and how squatters and railroads impacted rights on the ground. Variability in these factors implied locationally-specific differences in the relative bargaining power of the parties, which in turn implied that the pace and terms of dispossession differed by location. Following this discussion, we introduce quantitative evidence that shows how treaty terms, and the process of cessions, reflected these changes in bargaining power.

Borders

The public domain—land owned by the federal government—was an ever-changing region, representing a boundary area between land sold at public auction or held by states or territories and the land of Indigenous nations. At any point in time, the public domain comprised land that had been surveyed and available for sale and land not yet surveyed and thus not yet available for sale. The expectation that this land would eventually move into private hands led some to squat illegally, putting pressure on both the federal government and Indigenous nations.

Borders are core to the definition of sovereignty. Land treaties with an Indigenous nation moved the physical border between the United States and that nation. Once transferred, the land had to be surveyed and sections registered by surveyors at the land office. Only then was it brought to public auction.Footnote 26 The reality of defining borders was complex, as an excerpt from a treaty with the Creek from 1790 illustrates:

Beginning where the old line strikes the river Savannah; then up the said river to a place on the most northern branch …, commonly called the Keowee, where a NE. line to be drawn from the top of the Occunna mountain; thence to the source of the main south branch of the Oconee river, called the Appalachee; thence down the middle of the said main south branch and river Oconee to its confluence with the Oakmulgee, which form the Altamaha; and thence down the middle of the Altamaha to the old line on the said river, and then along the said old line to river St. Mary’s. The Creek cede all claim N. and E. of the foregoing boundaries.Footnote 27

Demarcation of boundary lines was vital in reducing potential disputes, but it required knowing the exact location of the “confluence” or the “top of the Occunna mountain.” These issues bedeviled surveyors as they sought to turn physical descriptors into a rectangular grid.Footnote 28 The reality was a survey-to-auction process that could take years.

Guarding the interest of the nation meant guarding the integrity of these treaty boundaries. For example, Commissioner Josiah Meigs (24 May 1817) wrote to Lewis Cass, Governor of the Michigan Territory, noting Indigenous concerns that the reservation rights were not being respected, especially those that “hold scites (sic) of ancient villages.” Cass required that the area be surveyed “with references to these villages and not merely with reference to the artificial lines of the general survey”Footnote 29 and “if possible done in a manner satisfactory to the Indians themselves” hiring an interpreter to satisfy Indian concerns.Footnote 30

Although Cass emphasized the integrity of Indigenous territory in Michigan, by 1838 Indigenous Michigan communities were being encouraged to move further west. Most refused, stating: “We do not wish to go West: we object to it entirely: this is all we have to say.”Footnote 31 In the end, only 651 people moved west from an Indigenous population of 7,600–8,300. By 1850, there were 6,000 Indigenous living on reservation land—the L’Arbre Croche and Grand River reservations—or on land purchased in public land sales with funds saved from annuity payments for land ceded.Footnote 32

The Michigan correspondence documents in microcosm how the federal government sought to uphold its treaty obligations; at the same time, it reveals that the reservation provisions were seen as impermanent. Indigenous communities in Michigan more successfully resisted removal than nations in other locations probably because, given land quality, resources, and climate, demand for land was lower than in regions such as Georgia.

Supreme Court—The Marshall Trilogy

In the 1790 Non-intercourse Act, the federal government declared Indigenous territory to be the sovereign jurisdiction of tribal nations, but this position shifted gradually until, in 1871, Congress declared it would no longer treat with Indigenous nations. Subsequent land acquisitions would be accomplished solely by Executive action and statute. Banner (Reference Banner2005) argues that between 1790 and 1830, two determinant factors transformed a view of Indigenous property rights from sovereign freehold ownership until ceded, to rights only of occupancy, and then to rights of occupancy that could be unilaterally terminated by the U.S. federal government.Footnote 33 One was the growing (physical) distance between decision makers and local populations at the frontier. The second was the pressure that squatters on un-surveyed territory put on Congress. These forces had, however, to be supported by the law.

Three landmark Supreme Court decisions (the “Marshall Trilogy” decisions in 1823, 1831, and 1832) are widely viewed as key for the changed federal position on Indian land title and sovereignty. Banner, however, argues that an earlier decision, Fletcher v Peck, 10 US 87 (1810), in which the Court recognized Georgia’s right to sell a future right to land that had not been ceded, began the alteration of the legal landscape.Footnote 34 In his decision, Chief Justice Marshall argued that the existence of Indian title did not preclude the legislature from granting the land subject to that title (undefined in the decision)—essentially laying out Georgia’s Right to Preemption. Dissenting Justice Johnson argued that Georgia had only the right to grant a fee-simple title when the proprietors should agree to sell. Despite the brevity of the Fletcher decision, it was influential in subsequent cases (Watson Reference Watson2012, p. 273).

In Johnson v M’Intosh (21 US 543 (1823)), both Johnson and M’Intosh claimed title to the same land in Illinois—Johnson having purchased it from Indian nations in 1773 and 1775, while M’Intosh claimed purchase from the federal government in 1818. The Chief Justice found in favor of M’Intosh consequentially crafting “a new judicial philosophy for Indigenous subordination,” (Ford Reference Ford2010, p. 136). Marshall argued that “[Indigenous nations] were admitted to be the rightful occupants of the soil, with a legal as well as just claim to retain possession of it, and to use it according to their own discretion; but their rights to complete sovereignty, as independent nations, were necessarily diminished, and their power to dispose of the soil at their own will, to whosoever they pleased, was denied by the original fundamental principle, that discovery gave exclusive title to those who made it” [i.e., Europeans].Footnote 35

Less than ten years later, using the premise that federal acquisition and sale of Indian lands was too slow, Georgia passed legislation to acquire Cherokee territory. In response, the Cherokee took the case to the Supreme Court.Footnote 36 In Cherokee Nation v Georgia, (30 US 1 (1831)), the Cherokee nation asked the Supreme Court to nullify Georgia’s action by virtue of Article 3 of the Constitution, which gives the Court jurisdiction over cases “between a State or the citizens thereof, and foreign states, citizens, or subjects.” Following on previous rulings, Chief Justice John Marshall wrote that the Cherokee nation was neither a “state” nor a “Foreign nation” but rather a “domestic dependent nation” and that while the Court could determine who owned a piece of land, it would not control the broader legislative power of a state. The next year, in Worcester v Georgia (31 US 515 (1832)), the Court argued that while the laws of the state of Georgia had no force in the territory of the Cherokee nation due to the inherent sovereignty of the Cherokee nation, such sovereignty did not constrain the state of Georgia in its removal of the Cherokee Nation (Banner Reference Banner2005, p. 222). An action supported by President Andrew Jackson. In 1830, Congress passed the Indian Removal Act (4 Stat. 411), permitting the exchange of lands west of the Mississippi for Indigenous lands within state borders (see Table 1). Significantly, for the first time, the legislation appropriated funds to support such “removal.”

Cherokee lands were valuable.Footnote 37 They were cultivated and productive and, in the early 1830s, a gold discovery on part of the Nation’s territory further increased their value. In 1835, in response to state pressure to sell, Georgia, in contravention of federal statute, signed the Treaty of New Echota with a group of Cherokee who voluntarily agreed to move. Although the Nation argued that the treaty was invalid, and it was not valid under Cherokee and U.S. law, the federal government stated that it could not protect the Cherokee and allowed the Army to march Indigenous members of the Five Tribes still living in Georgia to Oklahoma in the now-infamous “trail of tears” (Calloway Reference Calloway2013, pp. 121, 151; Gregg and Wishart Reference Gregg and Wishart2012).

The Marshall cases changed U.S. legal recognition of Indigenous title to the land from that of a sovereign nation to domestic dependent nation, changing relative bargaining power between Indigenous communities and the federal government.

Land Policies and Squatting

Settler pressure for land showed up in part through court cases and pressure on Congress, and more directly on the frontier through conflict between Indigenous nations, squatters, and government agencies on the ground.

The slow pace of land sales combined with the price of land contributed to the scale of squatting. Surveying and registering ceded land took time, and an initial auction price per acre ($1) and the large minimum plot size (680 acres) meant land was generally unaffordable for settler families. Despite changes in price and quantity minimums, land remained unobtainable for many. In 1820, for example, the price was $1.25 for a minimum of 80 acres but cash-only terms. In 1820, the agricultural wage in Massachusetts was $1.00 a day. As the white settler population grew, from natural increase and immigration, from under 3 million in 1780 to 38 million by 1870, growing particularly rapidly in the 1840s and 1850s, the demand for land put more pressure on the boundary between Indigenous land and already ceded land, whether surveyed or un-surveyed.Footnote 38 Non-Indigenous population density, shown for selected census years in Figure 4, maps the expanding white settler population.Footnote 39 While an individual squatter might not know, and perhaps could not know, where the boundary between the public domain and Indigenous territory exactly lay, squatting increased tension and conflict.

Figure 4 NON-INDIGENOUS U.S. POPULATION DENSITY (PERSONS PER SQUARE MILE SELECTED DECADES)

Notes: Lightest to darkest: under 0.01; under 2, 2–5, 6–17, 18–44, 45–90, and 91 and over.

Source: Bazzi, Fiszbein, and Gebresilasse (Reference Bazzi, Fiszbein and Gebresilasse2020). See Reference Carlos, Feir and RedishCarlos, Feir, and Redish (2022) and Online Appendix for further discussion.

Squatting was illegal. In 1807, Congress passed legislation allowing the use of military force to remove squatters to protect federal and Indian lands. Though rarely used, it indicated a desire to enforce the border, but as population numbers grew, squatters gained political power and successfully lobbied for preemption rights, which encouraged further squatting (Allen Reference Allen1991; Kanazawa Reference Kanazawa1996; Gailmard and Jenkins Reference Gailmard and Jenkins2018). Congress initially responded with legislation pertaining to particular groups or locations. Then, in 1830, the first of a set of two-year general preemption acts (1832, 1834, 1838) was passed, and finally, in 1841, a permanent preemption act (see Table 1). These acts legalized squatting and permitted an individual squatter first right to buy 160 acres at the minimum price when the land came to auction.Footnote 40 The Homestead Act of 1862 is, perhaps, the culmination of the acceptance of squatting.Footnote 41 Allen (Reference Allen1991, Reference Allen2019) argues that after the Civil War, the federal government used homesteading to direct settlement selectively to particular areas where it saw a greater Indigenous threat or power in order to put pressure on those communities that had not yet ceded their territory, thereby affecting the power structure between Indigenous and non-Indigenous peoples.

Railways

Pressure on Indigenous communities and their land was further exacerbated by railway development (Gates Reference Gates1968). We focus here on perhaps the most iconic railroad, the Union Pacific.Footnote 42 Non-Indigenous population growth in the Midwest and along the Pacific coast drove a demand to connect the two coasts, separated by Indigenous territory, resulting in the passage of the Pacific Railroad Act in 1862 (12 Stat. 489). The Act supported the financing of the construction of the railroad by granting the company land in alternate sections along the route. Thus the railroad did not just cross through Indigenous territory but brought settlers to those territories, bringing the United States into direct conflict with major nations of the Great Plains.

It is frequently noted that the Union Pacific Act and the Homestead Act were passed in 1862 in a Congress comprising only northern (Union) States, yet few comment on the fact that the projected route traversed land not in the public domain in 1862, that is, traversed Indigenous land (White Reference White2011, p. 25).Footnote 43 Congress recognized this. The Act states that “the United States shall extinguish as rapidly as may be the Indian Titles to all lands falling under the operation of this act and required for the said right of way and grants hereinafter made” (12 Stat.489). Figure 5 shows the footprint of the railroad from the passing of the Act to the completion of the railroad, which was lined by the land grants. Even with the rapid pace of land cessions, part of the route in Nevada crossed land not yet ceded when the line was completed in 1869.Footnote 44

Figure 5 ROUTE OF THE COMPLETED UNION PACIFIC AND CENTRAL PACIFIC RAILROAD

Source: See the text.

By the 1860s, the bargaining power of Indigenous nations had declined and, perhaps because of this, Congress began to question the treaty process. The House of Representatives opposed the treaty process, arguing that it enabled the Indian Office to work with the Senate, removing House jurisdiction over what should be public lands. At the same time, the House was routinely asked to approve appropriations for treaty financial commitments. In 1870, the House proposed an amendment to an appropriations bill that would have ended treaty making with Indigenous nations, but that bill was defeated in conference. In 1871, a one-line rider to an appropriations bill stated that “no Indian nation or tribe within the territory of the United States shall be acknowledged or recognized as an independent nation, tribe or power with whom the United States may contract by treaty” (16 stat. 566 (1871)). This ended formal treaty making by the federal government with Indigenous nations. Subsequently, land became part of the public domain through unilateral executive orders of the President or by statute (Spirling Reference Spirling2012). Indigenous nations could now essentially acquiesce, try to work within the U.S. political system, or fight.

VIOLENCE, THE EVOLUTION OF POWER, AND TREATY TERMS

Violence and war, implicit or actual, were a threat point in all treaty negotiations and occurred throughout the century.Footnote 45 We define war (distinct from violence) as the use of soldiers maintained and paid from federal revenues. Violence and its threat occurred at a more local level. Skirmishes between individuals on both sides of the frontier reflected either attempts at redistribution or a willful disregard of property rights and could lead to war—for example, the Seminole wars (1835–42) or the Rogue River Wars (1855–56).Footnote 46 There was also state-sponsored violence, such as scalp bounties as in California (1859), Minnesota (1863), Arizona (1864), or the use of the U.S. Army in “removing” the Cherokee nation from Georgia in the 1830s. While the threat of violence/war was always present, its scale was tied to the particulars of time and place.

In the early Republic, Indigenous nations held a military advantage. In 1816, Secretary of War, William H. Crawford, reiterated to military commanders that squatting was not to be condoned: “Intrusions upon the lands of the friendly Indian tribes, is not only a violation of the laws, but in direct opposition to the policy of the government towards its savage neighbors” (cited in Prucha Reference Prucha1962, p. 139). Over time, the rights and protections afforded to Indigenous nations, pressure on resources, and the presence of a standing army after the Civil War led to increasing skirmishes, battles, and long-running warfare in the Great Plains and along the southwest border with Mexico.Footnote 47

If treaty negotiations held the potential for violence, borders were flashpoints. In Figure 6, we map Paulin’s (1932) subset of major U.S.- Indigenous battles by decade from the Revolution to 1890 (i.e., all we were able to geocode—101 of his 160 battles), supplemented with additional information on both the Apache and Rogue River Wars. The figure illustrates the geographical shifts in conflict over the nineteenth century, mapping into the shifting border. Of course, this subset vastly understates the true level of violence.Footnote 48 Thus violence, as pointed out by Anderson and McChesney (Reference Anderson and McChesney1994), was a critical part of the evolution of the distribution of property rights and political jurisdiction in the United States.

Figure 6 U.S. MILITARY BATTLES AND THE FRONTIER

Notes: Figure shows only battles we could geocode by decade: lightest to darkest: 1790–1800, 1801–1820, 1821–1840, 1841–1860, 1861–1870, and 1871–1890. This figure underestimates violence and battles in which the U.S. military were involved.

Sources: Paulin (Reference Paulin1932) plus the Apache Wars and the Rogue River Wars.

The Evolution of Power and Treaty Terms

We have argued that jurisprudence, the pressure of squatting, and demand for and from railroads, individually and collectively, altered relative bargaining power. To provide empirical evidence of declining bargaining power on the part of Indigenous nations, we bring together data on land transfers, settler population density, and treaty terms.

First, we document that land was more likely to be transferred from an Indigenous nation to the United States when neighbor settler population density increased, even conditional on local settler population density. To do this, we combine measures of settler population density (by 2010 county) at the start of each decade with land transfer data—taking the first year any of the land in a county was ceded—to estimate the effect that settler population density had on the likelihood that land would be transferred between an Indigenous nation and the U.S. government. Using the data from 1790–1871, we estimate a cox-proportional hazard model of the probability of a land transfer between an Indigenous nation and the federal government as a function of neighbor-county settler population density, conditional on own-county population density.

The estimating equation is A(y) = A(y 0)e , where A(y 0) is the baseline hazard (probability) of a transfer, A(y) the hazard of transfer, and x a vector of: own-county settler population density at the start of the decade (binned at the levels of under 2 settlers per square mile, 2 to 6, 6 to 18, and 18–45), the maximum neighbor-county settler density at the start of the decade, and the natural log of the square area of the county.Footnote 49 The results are quite stark. Figure 7 (summary statistics in Table 2) shows that even low settler density in a neighboring county increased the probability that land would be transferred in a given decade. U.S. population growth and a concomitant demand for land increased pressure on Indigenous territory.

Figure 7 PROBABILITY LAND NOT CEDED

Note: Census 2010 U.S. county files used as geographic unit.

Sources: See the text and Figure 3.

Table 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS—LAND TRANSFER AND POPULATION DENSITY

Notes: Summary statistics underlying Figure 7. Considers counties with a first transfer date 1790– 1871. Means (standard deviations)

Sources: Bazzi, Fiszbein, and Gebresilasse (Reference Bazzi, Fiszbein and Gebresilasse2020) and Saunt (Reference Saunt2014).

Settler population pressures could have increased Indigenous bargaining power in a situation of strong property rights or limited sovereignty spillovers by increasing the value of their land. However, analysis by Spirling (Reference Spirling2012) suggests that this was not the case. He conducted a principal components analysis of the text in negotiated contracts and created an index using the extent of conciliatory versus harsh language. Spirling’s analysis encompassed all Treaties, Executive actions, and statutes from 1784 to 1911 that transferred Indigenous land into U.S. jurisdiction—including those rejected or unratified by Congress.Footnote 50 His delineation of each agreement is depicted in Figure 8.51 The index shows a decline over the nineteenth century suggesting a worsening of terms for Indigenous communities. Spirling’s analysis and our results—that there was an increasing likelihood of transfer with increased neighboring settler population density—are consistent with Indigenous nations experiencing decreasing bargaining power and ability to assert their claim to rights and valuable resources.

Figure 8 EROSION OF AGREEMENT TERMS

Notes: See the text.

Source: Spirling (Reference Spirling2012).

Spirling’s data includes rejected treaties. Once a treaty was signed by Indigenous nations and U.S. officials, the contract was not necessarily upheld. One example is the 18 Treaties signed in 1851 (in the aftermath of the Treaty of Guadalupe Hidalgo) when more than 100 California nations ceded approximately 66.5 million acres while retaining approximately 8.5 million acres in exchange for retained rights and resources (Flushman and Barbieri 1985; Deloria and DeMallie Reference Deloria and DeMallie1999; Miller Reference Miller2013). California, however, held the balance of power in the Senate. As a result, these treaties were not ratified, indeed they were hidden away, and

California nations lost their land without compensation. Senator Weller explained:

“We who represent the state of California were compelled, from a sense of duty, to vote for the rejection of the treaties, because we knew it would be utterly impossible for the General Government to retain these Indians in the undisturbed possession of these reservations. Why, there were as many as six reservations made in a single county . . . and that one of the best mining counties in the State. They knew that these reservations included mineral lands, and that, just so soon as it became profitable to dig upon the reservations than elsewhere, the white man would go there, and that the whole Army of the United States could not expel the intruders.”Footnote 52

The rejection of treaties that Indigenous nations had thought binding and the re-contracting of already signed treaties were not atypical. A growing body of historiography indicates that much (but not all) of this re-contracting was driven by the breaking of treaty terms or agreements by the United States, generally to reduce the size of Indigenous territory (Banner Reference Banner2005; Hämäläinen Reference Hämäläinen2019) as in the reduction of the Great Sioux reservation in the Dakotas with the discovery of mineral resources. In Figure 9, we depict the number of times a treaty was re-contracted in a specific 2010 county as measured by the number of “land transfer actions” from the Royce data depicted in Figure 3—the lightest color represents counties with one transaction, while the darkest represents counties transacted on five times (whether by treaty, statute, or Executive action).

Figure 9 TREATY RE-CONTACTING: 1783 TO 1900

Notes: Number of times a county transacted on—either through Treaty, Executive Order, or Statute. Lightest = 1, darkest = 5. Dark regions in Texas and East not included in Royce. Data for the Dakota’s were added to Royce’s data.

Source: See Figure 3.

We have taken treaties as a foundation for our analysis but do so acknowledging that treaties lay on a spectrum from freely negotiated to signed under duress and that treaty terms may have been understood differently by the parties. Regardless, by the late nineteenth century, the ability of most Indigenous nations to enforce treaty terms had diminished significantly. The complexity of the expansion of the jurisdiction of the United States, its economic consequences, and its connection to the treaty process warrants a significant body of literature within economics, and we hope our preliminary analysis here stimulates future research.

U.S. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT: GOOD INSTITUTIONS AND INDIGENOUS NATIONS

The standard narrative of nineteenth-century U.S. economic development revolves around access to land and good institutions. Acemoglu (Reference Acemoglu2003, p. 29) argues that “in colonies where there was little to be extracted, where most of the land was empty, where the disease environment was favorable, Europeans settled in large numbers and developed laws and institutions to ensure that they themselves were protected … In these colonies, the institutions were therefore much more conducive to investment and economic growth.” Sokoloff and Engerman (Reference Sokoloff and Engerman2000, p. 224) write that “In the United States, where there were never major obstacles to acquiring land, the terms of land acquisition became even easier over the course of the nineteenth century,” while the practice of “offering small units of land for disposal and maintaining open immigration” (p. 224) crafted an institutional environment conducive to strong property rights, greater equality, and growth than elsewhere in the Americas. There were, in the 1850s, political reactions to the scale of immigration, exemplified by the Know Nothing Party, and to the expansion of slavery, exemplified in the “Free Soiler” movement. However, these reflected a reaction against the distribution of gains and not against the institutions.

Good institutions protecting individual property rights and creating a level playing field does not describe the rules of the game faced by Indigenous nations, for whom rules changed and contracts were “re-negotiated.” Land for white settlers and open immigration were mirrored in diminishing land resources and opportunities for Indigenous nations. One might equally characterize the United States as an extractive regime built on the expropriation of Indigenous and African resources for the unchecked interests of powerful groups (Derenoncourt Reference Derenoncourt, Heather Boushey, DeLong and Steinbaum2017).

Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2002) claim that global evidence of a “reversal of fortunes” supports their argument for good institutions: for example, an originally poor continental United States became rich as a result of English settlers bringing good institutions to an empty land. Their empirical analysis, however, uses highly aggregated national data. Maloney and Caicedo (2016) re-examine this claim using disaggregated data at the state or provincial level across the Americas. They find that states or provinces that were heavily populated prior to colonization remain the most densely populated/wealthiest today. This finding implies no local reversal of fortune and possibly that “locational externalities and agglomeration externalities” dominate the effect of institutions (p. 2016). We shift the analysis to an even more micro level and compare population densities in 1500 to current densities at the census tract level within the United States. Our results are shown in Figures 10 (a) and (b). Plotting estimated Indigenous population densities for 1500 against current U.S. population density, we find (see Figure 10 (a)) that densely populated localities are still densely populated today. However, when we plot density estimates for 1500 against the current Indigenous population, we find a local reversal of fortune for Indigenous nations (see Figure 10 (b)). Wealthy locations in 1500 are wealthy today, but with settler populations. These findings are consistent with our broader narrative and suggest that institutions did not create wealth per se—rather, they redistributed productive assets to the advantage of settler populations and the disadvantage of Indigenous nations.

Figure 10 PERSISTENCE OR REVERSAL

Note: Binned scatter plots of pre-colonial population density on modern income by census tract.

Sources: American Community Survey 2014–2018 and HYDE version 3.2, 1500.

CONCLUSION

The United States was not empty when Europeans arrived, and Indigenous people did not simply die or disappear. Indigenous nations held sovereignty over the land, and their possession was reflected in improvements ranging from urban agglomerations to settled farms. Indigenous nations initially sold lands to individual settlers and then engaged in transfers with other sovereign nations, states, and colonies. For the first decades of the Republic, the balance of power lay with Indigenous nations. We argue that over the nineteenth century, underlying forces such as immigration policy, squatting, jurisprudence, railroads, and military power eroded the power of Indigenous nations, and we provide quantitative evidence to support the descriptive analysis. Accurately depicting U.S. economic development requires a multi-sided understanding of the source of “resource abundance” and the role of “good institutions.”

This paper argues that Indigenous nations are not tangential to U.S. economic development. A more inclusive economic history raises important questions and counterfactuals.Footnote 53 How essential was the expropriation of Indigenous resources for modern, largely White prosperity? Would honoring Indian sovereignty have reduced the land available to white settlers, or would secure property rights on the part of Indigenous nations have led to other forms of tenure such as leasehold to white tenants on Indian land? Although we do not discuss the price of land ceded, how might market valued treaties have changed current income inequality? Indeed, what might have been the composition of economic activity in this alternate universe? What would have been the impact on immigration and settlement patterns? A new cohort of historians has begun to raise such questions. Connolly (Reference Connolly2020, Reference Connolly2021), as one example, examines the role of state bond purchases by Indian trust funds in financing railways and banks, and the role of Indigenous land transfers in financial crises (1819, 1837).

Economic history depends on available data, and available data for Indigenous people are scant. The census did not include Indians until 1860, and even then did not include those living on reserved lands and Indigenous territory. Indians living on reservations were included only from 1900. None were deemed U.S. citizens until 1924. Even the use of maps for visualizing data, as we do here, is problematic.Footnote 54 While they do effectively convey the broad picture of the expansion of the U.S. public domain and shrinkage of Indigenous territory, they imply a certainty to boundaries, many of which remain disputed. However, an absence of easily obtainable and imperfect data has been a challenge economic historians have faced successfully before, so this should not be an excuse for the omission of Indigenous nations from the story of U.S. economic development.

American economic history must incorporate the process of territorial acquisition rather than starting from a narrative of an abundant empty land populated by small farmers with good institutions. Such a narrative is inaccurate and incomplete and provides a flawed basis upon which to draw conclusions about the quality of institutions and their role in American economic growth. It also erases a people and their histories and undermines a true accounting of the costs of economic development of the United States. We hope that this paper leads to more inclusive models of colonization more broadly and a better understanding of the United States and Indigenous economic growth.

Footnotes

We thank Douglas Allen, Terry Anderson, William Collins, Ellora Derenoncourt, Rob Hancock, Taylor Jaworski, Maggie Jones, Gloria Main, Cherie Metcalf, Pamela Nickless, Krishna Pendakur, Claudio Saunt (including for generously sharing his data), Richard Todd, and David Scoones for comments on an earlier draft of the paper; also the seminar participants at Yale University, UC Berkeley, the University of Pittsburgh, the Irish Quantitative History Meetings, and the University of Victoria. We especially thank the Editor, Eric Hilt, for his invaluable comments and suggestions. The usual caveat applies. We also thank Kit Schwartz, Hena Matthias, and Erin Song for thoughtful and careful research assistance and the University of British Columbia for financial support. The opinions and interpretations in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

1 See Oxford Handbook of American Economic History (Cain, Fishback, and Rhode Reference Cain, Fishback and Rhode2018, p. 1).

2 Cain, Fishback, and Rhode (Reference Cain, Fishback and Rhode2018, pp. 1, 4, 13).

3 We refer the interested reader to a quickly growing body of literature by historians, in particular, Banner (Reference Banner2005), Hämäläinen (Reference Hämäläinen2008, Reference Hämäläinen2019), Greer (Reference Greer2018), and Rao (Reference Rao2020).

4 We use Indigenous, Native American, and Indian interchangeably.

5 Figure A1 in the Online Appendix demonstrates that Indigenous nations are among the poorest populations in North America and income growth in recent years has been limited.

6 Democracy in America, vol. 2, pt 3, ch 21 (1840) p. 1140.

7 The word property is problematic but used here because of its familiarity to economists and its centrality to most economic development narratives. We acknowledge that it may not adequately convey the full relationship of people to place, and implies a separability that may not exist (Trosper Reference Trosper2020).

8 Exceptions include Anderson and McChesney (Reference Anderson and McChesney1994) and Allen and Leonard (Reference Allen and Leonard2021).

9 Examples include Hornbeck (Reference Hornbeck2010); Miller (Reference Miller2011); Bleakley and Ferrie (Reference Bleakley and Ferrie2016); Mattheis and Raz (Reference Mattheis and Raz2019); Bazzi, Fiszbein, and Gebresilasse (Reference Bazzi, Fiszbein and Gebresilasse2020). We do not intentionally single out these authors; rather we present these papers as typical of the approach taken in the discipline.

10 Perhaps the only paper in economic history that explicitly addresses the evolution of property ownership and sovereignty between the United States and Indigenous nations is Anderson and McChesney (Reference Anderson and McChesney1994).

11 On the Dawes Act, see Akee (Reference Akee2020), Carlson (Reference Carlson1978, Reference Carlson1981, Reference Carlson1983), Miller (Reference Miller2015), Dippel and Frye (Reference Dippel and Frye2021), Dippel, Frye, and Leonard (Reference Dippel, Frye and Leonard2020), and Leonard, Parker, and Anderson (Reference Leonard, Parker and Anderson2020). Exceptions include Wishart (Reference Wishart1995), Gregg (Reference Gregg2009), and Gregg and Wishart (Reference Gregg and Wishart2012) on the Cherokee economy and their removal.

12 This characterization is common among economists but more debated amongst legal scholars. See Merrill and Smith (2002).

13 The concepts of sovereignty and jurisdiction have been matters of long debate among legal historians. See, for example, Benton (Reference Benton2001, p. 279), Dennison (Reference Dennison2017), and Ford (Reference Ford2010).

14 The issues raised in this paragraph can be raised with respect to Indigenous nations’ laws.

15 Population size in 1492 is a matter of conjecture, as is the impact of disease. Recent scholarship argues that the impact of European diseases has been over-estimated (Larsen Reference Larsen1994; Cameron, Kelton, and Swedlund Reference Cameron, Kelton and Swedlund2015). Indigenous people continued to manage the land after the arrival of Europeans.

18 We focus only on English colonies.

19 Conflicts over land would continue, as colonists claimed title to land through indigenous wives and children (Borsk Reference Borsk2020).

20 This was not an Indian Reservation, as stated in Atack and Passell (Reference Atack and Passell1994, p. 251) rather recognized Indigenous sovereign territory.

21 The end of French sovereignty in the region did not mean the end of the threat from competing European powers.

22 “An act to regulate trade and intercourse with the Indian tribes” Act of 22 July 1790, Pub. L. No. c. 33 Stat. 137, 138. The act also provided that any U.S. citizen who committed a crime per U.S. law in Indian territory would be punished under U.S. law, not Indian law.

23 The bow and arrow was more accurate, reliable, and quicker to re-load than guns (Gwynne Reference Gwynne2010; Silverman Reference Silverman2016). The United States unsuccessfully prohibited the sale of firearms to Indigenous people (Blocher and Carberry Reference Blocher and Carberry2020).

24 See Lee (Reference Lee2017) for a detailed analysis of the costs of acquiring the Louisiana lands from Indigenous owners.

25 Land transfers were compiled by the Bureau of American Ethnology in 1899 under the guidance of Charles C. Royce, digitized by Saunt (Reference Saunt2014). The 1850s land transfers in California never ratified by Congress are discussed in the fifth section. Nuances such as these are often lost in depictions of these data.

26 Claims issued to French and Spanish settlers prior to a treaty had also to be adjudicated. See Territorial Papers of the United States, Vol. 10 for a discussion of this issue. Lewandoski (Reference Lewandoski2019) documents how some Indigenous communities acquired title from France, or Spain, or Mexico.

27 See the Annual Report of the Bureau of American Ethnology to the Secretary of the Smithsonian Institution, p. 652 of 997, 7 August 1790. Libecap and Lueck (Reference Libecap and Lueck2011) on metes and bounds.

28 See, for example, Edward Tiffin to Josiah Meigs, 4 October 1817, pages 706–708, The Territorial Papers of the United States, v. 10.

29 Territorial Papers, v. 10, p. 699.

30 Pearce (Reference Pearce2004, pp. 138,144, 148) and Nichols (Reference Nichols2018) show the survey to be off grid. Surveyors were reminded not to trespass on Indigenous territory in any of their work.

31 Quoted in Neumeyer (Reference Neumeyer1971, p. 280). The experience of the Michigan communities is another example of what Lewandoski (Reference Lewandoski2019) calls “small nations”—those able to use the U.S. legal system to obtain legal title.

32 Territorial Papers, vol .10, pp. 275, 278, 281, 283. Annuity payments brought monies into the region.

33 This is a large and complex issue. Our discussion largely follows Banner (Reference Banner2005).

34 Peck’s lawyer, arguing for Georgia’s right to sell Indian land, described “Indian title” as “a mere occupancy for the purpose of hunting. It is not like our tenures; they have no idea of a title to the soil itself. It is overrun by them, rather than inhabited …” (c.94) His argument completely ignored the reality that the Cherokee were (slave-owning) farmers.

35 U.S. Reports: Johnson v. McIntosh, 21 U.S. (8 Wheat.) 543 (1823); p. 574. Italics added.

36 Ablavsky (Reference Ablavsky2016) discusses Indigenous use of U.S. federal courts and legal structures to assert their rights and sovereignty in the early Republic.

37 Wishart (Reference Wishart1995), using data from the 1835 Cherokee census, demonstrates that the Cherokee produced surpluses in excess of subsistence requirements.

38 See Carter et al. (Reference Carter, Gartner, Haines, Olmstead, Sutch and Wright2006, table Aa7), the Historical Statistics of the United States, Millennial Edition.

39 All analyses of county data use 2010 county borders. See the Online Appendix for a discussion of the impact of using 2010 county borders for historical analysis.

40 In contrast to preemption rights, the Right of Preemption deals with the rights of the government, federal or state.

41 Title was not transferred until the conditions of the Act were met and registered at the Land Office.

42 We use the term to include the Central Pacific section from the west coast to Promontory Point, Utah.

43 Other legislation passed in 1862 included the Morrill Act, which granted public lands to universities (Lee and Ahtone (Reference Lee and Ahtone2020) and Reference Ehrlich, Cook and YinEhrlich, Cook, and Yin (2018)) and legislation (25 USC 72), which permitted the President to abrogate treaties with Indian tribes in hostility with the United States.

44 The route through California traversed land ceded in treaties negotiated but not ratified by Congress. The land area taken by the railroad includes both the track bed and the land grant.

45 Umbeck (Reference Umbeck1981) argued that “might” shapes both the formation and distribution of property rights. Anderson and McChesney (Reference Anderson and McChesney1994) model the evolution of treaty making in an environment where the threat of violence and the relative beliefs about each other’s power changed over time.

46 We focus here only on Indigenous/U.S. battles, not war with other European nations or between Indigenous nations.

47 Even after demobilization, a standing army of 25,000 men remained, with one-third in the military division of Missouri.

48 Using U.S. military records from 1830 to 1897, Anderson (Reference Anderson2021) analyzes over 1,800 incidences of violent conflict between the U.S. military and Indian nations.

49 See the Online Appendix for further discussion.

50 A detailed discussion of these different forms of transfers can be found in Spirling (Reference Spirling2012).

51 Words such as friendship or peace (conciliatory) relative to relinquish or reservation (harsh). Treaty data from 1784 to 1911 based on 595 documents reported by Deloria and DeMallie (Reference Deloria and DeMallie1999)—see Spirling (Reference Spirling2012, p. 87). Even after the end of presidential treaty power in 1871, the language in land transfer contracts follows a similar trend (triangles).

52 Cited by Flushman and Barbieri (1985, p. 405); original, Cong. Globe 32nd Congress 1st sess 2173 (1852).

53 Similarly, Logan and Temin (Reference Logan and Temin2020) argue for a more inclusive American economic historiography that pays attention to where Black Americans were included and excluded from the story of U.S. economic growth.

54 Banner, for example, declined to illustrate his legal history of land dispossession with maps stating that they could not accurately capture the complexity of the history. And indeed, these data are inaccurate in specific detail, such as for California.

References

REFERENCES

Ablavsky, Gregory. “The Adjudicatory State: Sovereignty, Property, and Law in the U.S. Territories, 1783–1802.” Ph.D. diss., University of Pennsylvania, 2016.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron. “Root Causes: A Historical Approach to Assessing the Role of Institutions in Economic Development.Finance and Development 40, no. 2 (2003): 2730.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 4 (2002): 1231–94.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic Growth 1, edited by Aghion, Philippe and Steven, N. Durlauf, 385472. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2005.Google Scholar
Akee, Randall. “Land Titles and Dispossession: Allotment on American Indian Reservations.Journal of Economics, Race, and Policy 3, no. 2 (2020): 123–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akee, Randall K., and Taylor, Jonathan B.. Social and Economic Change on American Indian Reservations: A Databook of the US Censuses and American Community Survey, 1990–2010. Sarasota, FL: Taylor Policy Group, 2014. Download at taylorpolicy.com/us-databook (retrieved 28 December 2020).Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A.Property Rights.” In The World of Economics, edited by Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray , and Newman, Peter, 584–90. London: The Macmillan Press Limited, 1991.Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W.Homesteading and Property Rights; or, ‘How the West Was Really Won’.Journal of Law and Economics 34, no. 1 (1991): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Douglas W.Establishing Economic Property Rights by Giving Away an Empire.Journal of Law and Economics 62, no. 2 (2019): 251–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Douglas W., and Leonard, Bryan. “Late-Homesteading: Native Dispossession Through Strategic Occupation.Personal correspondence, March 2021.Google Scholar
Anderson, R. W.Politics, Economics, and Native American Conflicts.Australian Economic History Review, forthcoming, 2021.Google Scholar
Anderson, Terry L., and McChesney, Fred S.. “Raid or Trade? An Economic Model of Indian-White Relations.Journal of Law and Economics 37, no. 1 (1994): 3974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atack, Jeremy, and Passell, Peter. A New Economic History of American History. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 1994.Google Scholar
Banner, Stuart. How the Indians Lost Their Land: Law and Power on the Frontier. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bazzi, Samuel, Fiszbein, Martin, and Gebresilasse, Mesay. “Frontier Culture: The Roots and Persistence of ‘Rugged Individualism’ in the United States.Econometrica 88, no. 6 (2020): 2329–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, B. L.Property Rights and the Buffalo Economy of the Great Plains.” In Self-Determination: The Other Path for Native Americans, edited by Terry, L. Anderson, Bruce, L. Benson, and Thomas, E. Flanagan, 2967. Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Benton, Lauren. A Search for Sovereignty: Law and Geography in European Empires, 1400–1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Bleakley, Hoyt, and Ferrie, Joseph P.. “Shocking Behavior: Random Wealth in Antebellum Georgia and Human Capital across Generations.Quarterly Journal of Economics 131, no. 3 (2016): 1455–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blocher, Joseph, and Carberry, Caitlan. “Historical Gun Laws Targeting ‘Dangerous’ Groups and Outsiders.Duke Law School Public Law Legal Theory Series, no. 2020-80 (2020): 113.Google Scholar
Borrows, John, and Coyle, Michael. The Right Relationship: Reimagining the Implementation of Historical Treaties. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2017.Google Scholar
Borsk, Michael. “Conveyance between Kin: Settler States, Indigenous Nations, and the Politics of Property in North America after 1763.Queen’s University Department of History Working Paper, Kingston, Ontario, 2020.Google Scholar
Cain, Louis P., Fishback, Price V., and Rhode, Paul W., eds. Oxford Handbook of American Economic History, Volume 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Calloway, Colin G. Pen and Ink Witchcraft: Treaties and Treaty Making in American Indian History. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Cameron, Catherine, Kelton, Paul, and Swedlund, Alan, eds. Beyond Germs: Native Depopulation in North America . Amerind Studies in Archaeology. Tucson, AZ: University of Arizona Press, 2015.Google Scholar
Carlos, Ann M., Feir, Donna L., and Redish, Angela. “Indigenous Nations and the Development of the U.S. Economy: Land, Resources, and Dispossession.Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2022-02-2. https://doi.org/10.3886/E161181V1.Google Scholar
Carlos, Ann M., and Lewis, Frank D.. Commerce by a Frozen Sea: Native Americans and the European Fur Trade. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2010a.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlos, Ann M., and Lewis, Frank D.. “Property Rights, Standards of Living and Economic Growth: Western Canadian Cree.QED Working Paper No. 1232, Kingston, Ontario, 2010b.Google Scholar
Carlson, Leonard A.The Dawes Act and the Decline of Indian Farming.Journal of Economic History 38, no. 1 (1978): 274–76.Google Scholar
Carlson, Leonard A.Land Allotment and the Decline of American Indian Farming.Explorations in Economic History 18, no. 2 (1981): 128–54.Google Scholar
Carlson, Leonard A.Federal Policy and Indian Land: Economic Interests and the Sale of Indian Allotments, 1900–1934.Agricultural History 57, no. 1 (1983): 3345.Google Scholar
Carter, Susan B., Gartner, Scott S., Haines, Michael R., Olmstead, Alan L., Sutch, Richard, and Wright, Gavin, eds. Historical Statistics of the United States: Millennial Edition, Volume 3. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Connolly, Emilie. “Indian Trust Funds and the Routes of American Capitalism, 1795–1865.” Ph.D. diss., New York University, 2020.Google Scholar
Connolly, Emilie. “Panic, State Power, and Chickasaw Dispossession.Journal of the Early Republic 40, no. 4 (2021): 683–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Zwart, Pim, and van Zanden, Jan Luiten. The Origins of Globalization: World Trade in the Making of the Global Economy, 1500–1800. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Deloria, Vine, and DeMallie, Raymond J.. Documents of American Indian Diplomacy: Treaties, Agreements, and Conventions, 1775–1979, Volume 1. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. “Towards a Theory of Property Rights.” American Economic Review 57, no. 2 (1967): 347–59.Google Scholar
Denevan, William M.Epilogue.” In The Native Population of the Americas in 1492, edited by William, M. Denevan, 289–92. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Denevan, William M.The Pristine Myth: The Landscape of the Americas in 1492.Annals of the Association of American Geographers 82, no. 3 (1992): 369–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennison, Jean. “Entangled Sovereignties: The Osage Nation’s Interconnections with Governmental and Corporate Authorities.American Ethnologist 44, no. 4 (2017): 684–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Derenoncourt, Ellora. “The Historical Origins of Global Inequality.” In After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, edited by Heather Boushey, J. DeLong, Bradford, and Steinbaum, Marshall, 491511. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2017.Google Scholar
Dippel, Christian. “Forced Coexistence and Economic Development: Evidence from Native American Reservations.Econometrica 82, no. 6 (2014): 2131–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dippel, Christian, and Frye, Dustin. “The Effect of Land Allotment on Native American Households during the Assimilation Era.” Working Paper, 2021. Available at https://christiandippel.com/dawes_.pdf.Google Scholar
Dippel, Christian, Frye, Dustin, and Leonard, Brian. “Property Rights without Transfer Rights: A Study of Indian Land Allotment.” NBER Working Paper No. w27479, Cambridge, MA, July 2020.Google Scholar
Dobyns, Henry F. Their Number Become Thinned: Native American Population Dynamics in Eastern North America. Knoxville, TN: University of Tennessee Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Dunbar-Ortiz, Roxanne. An Indigenous Peoples’ History of the United States, Volume 3. Boston, MA: Beacon Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Isaac, Cook, Adam, and Yin, Yong. “What Accounts for the US Ascendancy to Economic Superpower by the Early Twentieth Century? The Morell Act-Human Capital Hypothesis.Journal of Human Capital 12, no. 2 (2018): 233–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, R. C.Property in Land.Yale Law Journal 102, no. 6 (1993): 1315–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feir, Donna, Gillezeau, Rob, and Jones, Maggie. “The Slaughter of the North American Bison and Reversal of Fortunes on the Great Plains.” Center for Indian Country Development Working Paper Series 1-2019, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Minneapolis, MN, 2019.Google Scholar
Flushman, Bruce S., and Barbieri, Joe. “Aboriginal Title: The Special Case of California.Pacific Law Journal 17 (1985–1986): 391460.Google Scholar
Ford, Lisa. Settler Sovereignty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frye, Dustin, and Parker, Dominic. “Indigenous Self-Governance and Development on American Indian Reservations.” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, forthcoming, 2021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gailmard, Sean, and Jenkins, Jeffery A.. “Distributive Politics and Congressional Voting: Public Lands Reform in the Jacksonian Era.Public Choice 175 (2018): 259–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gates, Paul Wallace. History of Public Land Law Development, Volume 62, Public Land Law Review Commission, 1968.Google Scholar
Greer, Allan. Property and Dispossession: Natives, Empires and Land in Early Modern North America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
Gregg, Matthew T.Technical Efficiency Estimates of Cherokee Agriculture: A Pre-and Post-Removal Analysis.Journal of Socio-Economics 38, no. 5 (2009): 826–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gregg, Matthew T.The Long-Term Effects of American Indian Boarding Schools.Journal of Development Economics 130, no. 1 (2018): 1732.Google Scholar
Gregg, Matthew T., and Wishart, David M.. “The Price of Cherokee Removal.Explorations in Economic History 49, no. 4 (2012): 423–42.Google Scholar
Gwynne, S. C. Empire of the Summer Moon: Quanah Parker and the Rise and Fall of the Comanches, the Most Powerful Indian Tribe in American History. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster, 2010.Google Scholar
Hämäläinen, Pekka. The Comanche Empire. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Hämäläinen, Pekka. Lakota America: A New History of Indigenous Power. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hornbeck, Richard. “Barbed Wire: Property Rights and Agricultural Development.Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, no. 2 (2010): 767810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jonathan R. T., Hughes, and Cain, Louis P.. American Economic History (8th edition). Pearson Series in Economics. New York: Pearson, 2010 Google Scholar
Isenberg, Andrew C. The Destruction of the Bison: An Environmental History, 1750–1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnsen, D. Bruce. “The Formation and Protection of Property Rights among the Southern Kwakiutl Indians.Journal of Legal Studies 15, no. 1 (1986): 4167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanazawa, Mark T.Possession Is Nine Points of the Law: The Political Economy of Early Public Land Disposal.Explorations in Economic History 33, no. 2 (1996): 227–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, Alexander, Brierley, Chris, Maslin, Mark M., and Lewis, Simon L.. “Earth System Impacts of the European Arrival and Great Dying in the Americas after 1492.” Quaternary Science Reviews 207, no. 1 (2019): 1336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi R.The Mystery of Property Rights: A US Perspective.Journal of Economic History 71, no. 2 (2011): 275306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larsen, Clark S.In the Wake of Columbus: Native Population Biology in the Post Contact Americas.American Journal of Physical Anthropology 37, no. S19 (1994): 109–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Robert. “Accounting for Conquest: The Price of the Louisiana Purchase of Indian Country.Journal of American History 103, no. 4 (2017): 921–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Robert, and Ahtone, Tristan. “Land-Grab Universities.” High Country News, March 2020. Available at https://www.hcn.org/issues/52.4/indigenous-affairs-education-land-grab-universities.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. “Property Rights in American History.” The Oxford Handbook of American Economic History, edited by Louis, P. Cain, Price, V. Fishback, and Paul, W. Rhode, vol. 2. Oxford Handbooks online, 2018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leonard, Bryan, Parker, Dominic P., and Anderson, Terry L.. “Land Quality, Land Rights, and Indigenous Poverty.Journal of Development Economics 143, no. 1 (2020): 102435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewandoski, Julia M.Small Victories: Indigenous Proprietors across Empires in North America, 1763–1891.” Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley, 2019.Google Scholar
Libecap, Gary D., and Lueck, Dean. “The Demarcation of Land and the Role of Coordinating Property Institutions.Journal of Political Economy 119, no. 3 (2011): 426–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Logan, Trevon, and Temin, Peter. “Inclusive American Economic History: Containing Slaves, Freedmen, Jim Crow Laws, and the Great Migration.Institute for New Economic Thinking Working Paper Series No. 110, New York, NY, January 2020.Google Scholar
Lutz, John S. Makúk: A New History of Aboriginal-White Relations. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Maloney, William F., and Valencia Caicedo, Felipe. “The Persistence of (Subnational) Fortune.Economic Journal 126, no. 598 (2016): 2363–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mann, Charles C. 1491: New Revelations of the Americas before Columbus. New York, NY: Vintage Books, 2005.Google Scholar
Marlene, Martin, M., and O’Leary, Timothy J.. Ethnographic Bibliography of North America. New Haven, CT: Human Relations Area Files Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Mattheis, Ross, and Raz, Itzchak T.. “There’s No Such Thing as Free Land: The Homestead Act and Economic Development.” Harvard University Working Paper, Cambridge, MA, 2019.Google Scholar
Merrill, Thomas W., and Smith, Henry E.. “What Happened to Property in Law and Economics?Yale Law Journal 111 (2001–2002): 357–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Larisa K. “The Secret Treaties with California’s Indians.” Prologue Magazine: Journal of the National Archives and Records Administration (2013): 3845.Google Scholar
Miller, Melinda. “Land and Racial Wealth Inequality.American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 101, no. 3 (2011): 371–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Melinda. “Dawes Cards and Indian Census Data.Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History 48, no. 4 (2015): 214–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, George R., and Chaplin, George. “Eastern North American Population at ca. A.D. 1500.American Antiquity 75, no. 4 (2010): 707–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neumeyer, Elizabeth. “Michigan Indians Battle against Removal.Michigan History 55, no. 4 (1971): 275–88.Google Scholar
Nichols, David A. Peoples of the Inland Sea: Native Americans and Newcomers in the Great Lakes Region, 1600–1870. Columbus, OH: Ohio University Press, 2018.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C.Institutions.Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 1 (1991): 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., Wallis, John J., and Weingast, Barry R.. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paulin, Charles. Atlas of the Historical Geography of the United States. New York, NY: American Geographical Society of New York, 1932.Google Scholar
Pearce, Margaret W.The Holes in the Grid: Reservation Surveys in Lower Michigan.Michigan Historical Review 30, no. 2 (2004): 135–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, Claire. Credit Nation: Property Laws and Institutions in Early America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2021.Google Scholar
Prucha, Francis P. American Indian Policy in the Formative Years. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Ramenofsky, Ann F. Vectors of Death: The Archaeology of European Contact. Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Rao, Gautham. “The New Historiography of the Early Federal Government: Institutions, Contexts, and the Imperial State.William and Mary Quarterly 77, no. 1 (2020): 97128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ray, Arthur J. Indians in the Fur Trade: Their Roles as Trappers, Hunters, and Middlemen in the Lands Southwest of Hudson Bay, 1660–1870. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1974.Google Scholar
Redish, Angela. “Treaty of Paris vs. Treaty of Niagara: Rethinking Canadian Economic History in the 21st Century.Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’Economique 52, no. 4 (2019): 1325–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rohrbough, Malcolm J. The Land Office Business: The Settlement and Administration of American Public Lands, 1789–1837, 2nd ed. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing Co., 1990.Google Scholar
Saunt, Claudio. “Invasion of America.” ArcGIS Online, 2014. Retrieved from https://usg.maps.arcgis.com/apps/webappviewer/index.html.Google Scholar
Silverman, David J. Thundersticks. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sokoloff, Kenneth L., and Engerman, Stanley L.. “Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World.Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 3 (2000): 217–32.Google Scholar
Spirling, Arthur. “U.S. Treaty Making with American Indians: Institutional Change and Relative Power, 1784–1911.American Journal of Political Science 56, no. 1 (2012): 8497.Google Scholar
Steckel, Richard H., and Prince, Joseph M.. “Tallest in the World: Native Americans of the Great Plains in the Nineteenth Century.American Economic Review 91, no. 1 (2001): 287–94.Google Scholar
Steckel, Richard H., and Rose, Jerome C.. The Backbone of History: Health and Nutrition in the Western Hemisphere. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taxay, Don. Money of the American Indians and Other Primitive Currencies of the Americas. Charleston, SC: Nabu Press 1970.Google Scholar
Thornton, Russell. American Indian Holocaust and Survival: A Population History since 1492. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Trosper, Ron. “Territory.” In The Principles of Indigenous Economics. Personal correspondence, 2020.Google Scholar
Ubelaker, Douglas H.North American Indian Population Size, AD 1500 to 1985.American Journal of Physical Anthropology 77, no. 3 (1988): 289–94.Google Scholar
Umbeck, John. “Might Makes Rights: A Theory of the Formation and Initial Distribution of Property Rights.Economic Inquiry 19, no. 1 (1981): 3859.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Commission on Civil Rights. “Broken Promises: Continuing Federal Funding Shortfall for Native Americans.” Technical report, Washington, DC, 2018.Google Scholar
Walker, Francis A., and United States Census Office (9th Census, 1870). Statistical Atlas of the United States Based on the Results of the Ninth Census with Contributions from Many Eminent Men of Science and Several Departments of the Government. New York, NY: J. Bien, lith, 1874.Google Scholar
Walton Gary, M., and Rockoff, Hugh. History of the American Economy (12th edition). New York: South-Western Cengage Learning, 2013.Google Scholar
Watson, Blake. Buying America from the Indians: Johnson v. McIntosh and the History of Native Land Rights. Norman, OK: University of Oklahoma Press, 2012.Google Scholar
White, Richard. Railroaded: The Transcontinentals and the Making of Modern America. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company, 2011.Google Scholar
Wishart, David M.Evidence of Surplus Production in the Cherokee Nation Prior to Removal.Journal of Economic History 55, no. 1 (1995): 120–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Gavin. “The Origins of American Industrial Success, 1879–1940.American Economic Review 80, no. 4 (1996): 651–68.Google Scholar
Zedeño, Maria N., Ballenger, Jesse A. M., and Murray, John R.. “Landscape Engineering and Organizational Complexity among Late Prehistoric Bison Hunters of the Northwestern Plains.Current Anthropology 55, no. 1 (2014): 2358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 THE SPATIAL DISTRIBUTION OF INDIGENOUS NATIONS 1600Source: Martin and O’Leary (1990).

Figure 1

Table 1 IMPORTANT U.S. LAND LEGISLATION

Figure 2

Figure 2 UNITED STATES ACQUISITION OF NEGOTIATION RIGHTSNotes: This map should be understood as U.S. acquisition of monopoly rights to treat with Indigenous nations. See, for example, Figures 9.1 Atack and Passell (1994); Map 8.1 Walton and Rockoff (2013); Figure 5.3 Hughes and Cain (2010).Source: National Geographic: Territorial Gains by the U.S. Maps of landed gained by the U.S. Accessed from https://www.nationalgeographic.org/photo/territorial-gains/, 26 February 2021.

Figure 3

Figure 3 LAND CESSION TREATIES TO 1871 (BY DECADE)Notes: Treaty transfers in dark; reservations depicted in light shade; eastern regions not included in Royce data; the 18 hidden treaties in in California depicted in a somewhat darker—see text. Use rights could be negotiated as a condition of transfer.Source: Bureau of American Ethnology in 1899 under the guidance of Charles C. Royce, digitized by Saunt (2014).

Figure 4

Figure 4 NON-INDIGENOUS U.S. POPULATION DENSITY (PERSONS PER SQUARE MILE SELECTED DECADES)Notes: Lightest to darkest: under 0.01; under 2, 2–5, 6–17, 18–44, 45–90, and 91 and over.Source: Bazzi, Fiszbein, and Gebresilasse (2020). See Carlos, Feir, and Redish (2022) and Online Appendix for further discussion.

Figure 5

Figure 5 ROUTE OF THE COMPLETED UNION PACIFIC AND CENTRAL PACIFIC RAILROADSource: See the text.

Figure 6

Figure 6 U.S. MILITARY BATTLES AND THE FRONTIERNotes: Figure shows only battles we could geocode by decade: lightest to darkest: 1790–1800, 1801–1820, 1821–1840, 1841–1860, 1861–1870, and 1871–1890. This figure underestimates violence and battles in which the U.S. military were involved.Sources: Paulin (1932) plus the Apache Wars and the Rogue River Wars.

Figure 7

Figure 7 PROBABILITY LAND NOT CEDEDNote: Census 2010 U.S. county files used as geographic unit.Sources: See the text and Figure 3.

Figure 8

Table 2 SUMMARY STATISTICS—LAND TRANSFER AND POPULATION DENSITY

Figure 9

Figure 8 EROSION OF AGREEMENT TERMSNotes: See the text.Source: Spirling (2012).

Figure 10

Figure 9 TREATY RE-CONTACTING: 1783 TO 1900Notes: Number of times a county transacted on—either through Treaty, Executive Order, or Statute. Lightest = 1, darkest = 5. Dark regions in Texas and East not included in Royce. Data for the Dakota’s were added to Royce’s data.Source: See Figure 3.

Figure 11

Figure 10 PERSISTENCE OR REVERSALNote: Binned scatter plots of pre-colonial population density on modern income by census tract.Sources: American Community Survey 2014–2018 and HYDE version 3.2, 1500.

Supplementary material: PDF

Carlos et al. supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Carlos et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.6 MB