Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T17:46:21.611Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Part I - Economics of Antitrust-IP

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 May 2017

Roger D. Blair
Affiliation:
University of Florida
D. Daniel Sokol
Affiliation:
University of Florida
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Arrow, KJ. 1962. Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention. In The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 609–25.Google Scholar
Brennan, TJ. 2007. Should Innovation Rationalize Supra-Competitive Prices? A Skeptical Speculation. In Fredenberg, A. (ed.), The Pros and Cons of High Prices. Stockholm: Konkurrensverket/Swedish Competition Authority, pp. 88127.Google Scholar
Carlton, D., Gans, JS., and Waldman, M.. 2010. Why Tie a Product Consumers Do Not Use? American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2(3), 85105.Google Scholar
Department of Justice. 2010. Horizontal Merger Guidelines: Proposed. Washington, DC: Mimeo.Google Scholar
Evans, DS. and Schmalensee, R.. 2002. Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis in Dynamically Competitive Industries. In Jaffe, A.B., Lerner, J. and Stern, S. (eds.), Innovation Policy and the Economy, Vol. 2, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, chapter 1.Google Scholar
Fisher, FM. 2000. The IBM and Microsoft Cases: What’s the Difference? American Economic Review, 90(2) 180–3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gans, JS. 2009. Negotiating for the Market. Melbourne: Mimeo.Google Scholar
Gans, J.S. 2010. When is Static Analysis a Sufficient Proxy for Dynamic Considerations? Reconsidering Innovation and Antitrust. In Lerner, J. and Stern, S. (eds.), Innovation Policy and the Economy, Vol. 11. Cambridge, MA: NBER.Google Scholar
Gans, J.S. 2013. Intel and Blocking Practices (2010). In Kwoka, J. and White, L. (eds.), The Antitrust Revolution, 6th edition. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gans, JS. and Persson, L.. 2013. Entrepreneurial Commercialization Choices and the Interaction between IPR and Competition Policy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22(1), 131–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gans, JS. and Stern, S.. 2000. Incumbency and R&D Incentives: Licensing the Gale of Creative Destruction. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 9(4), 485511.Google Scholar
Gans, J.S. and Stern, S.. 2003. The Product Market and the “Market for Ideas”: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs. Research Policy, 32(2), 333–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, R. 2006. Looking for Mr. Schumpeter: Where Are We in the Competition Innovation Debate? In Jaffe, Adam B., Lerner, Josh, and Stern, Scott (eds.), Innovation Policy and the Economy, 6, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Gilbert, R. 2007. Holding Innovation to an Antitrust Standard. Competition Policy International, 3, 4777.Google Scholar
Gilbert, R. and Newbery, D.. 1982. Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly. American Economic Review, 72(3), 514–26.Google Scholar
Manne, G. and Wright, J.. 2009. “Innovation and the Limits of Antitrust,” George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 09–54; Lewis & Clark Law School Legal Studies Research Paper No. 2009–26. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1490849.Google Scholar
Ordover, J. and Willig, R.. 1981. An Economic Definition of Predation: Pricing and Product Innovation. Yale Law Journal, 9, 853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasmussen, E. 1988. Entry for Buyout. Journal of Industrial Economics, 36(3), 281–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinganum, J.F. 1989. On the Timing of Innovation. In Schmalansee, R. and Willig, R. (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 849908.Google Scholar
Segal, I. and Whinston, M.. 2007. Antitrust in Innovative Industries. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1703–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, DJ. 1987. Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy. In Teece, DJ. (ed.), The Competitive Challenge: Strategies for Industrial Innovation and Renewal. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger, pp. 185220.Google Scholar

References

Addanki, Sumanth and Butler, Henry N.. 2014. Activating Actavis: Economic Issues in Applying the Rule of Reason to Reverse Payment Settlements. Minnesota Journal of Law, Science & Technology, 15(1), 7794.Google Scholar
Addanki, Sumanth and Daskin, Alan J.. 2008. Patent Settlement Agreements. ABA Section of Antitrust Law, 3, 2127–53.Google Scholar
Cotter, Thomas F. 2004. Antitrust Implications of Patent Settlements Involving Reverse Payments: Defending a Rebuttable Presumption of Illegality in Light of Some Recent Scholarship. Antitrust Law Journal, 71(3), 1069–97.Google Scholar
Cramer, Eric L. and Berger, Daniel. 2004. The Superiority of Direct Proof of Monopoly Power and Anticompetitive Effects in Antitrust Cases Involving Delayed Entry of Generic Drugs. University of San Francisco Law Review, 39, 81140.Google Scholar
Drake, Keith M., Starr, Martha A., and McGuire, Thomas. 2014. Do “Reverse Payment” Settlements of Brand-Generic Patent Disputes in the Pharmaceutical Industry Constitute an Anticompetitive Pay for Delay? NBER Working Paper No. 20292. July.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edlin, Aaron, Hemphill, Scott, Hovenkamp, Herbert, and Shapiro, Carl. 2013. Activating Actavis. Antitrust Magazine, 28(1), 1623.Google Scholar
Elhauge, Einer and Krueger, Alex. 2012. Solving the Patent Settlement Puzzle. Texas Law Review, 91, 283330.Google Scholar
Federal Trade Commission. 2006. Prepared Statement of the Federal Trade Commission Before the Special Committee on Aging of the United States Senate on Barriers to Generic Entry. Available at www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/prepared-statement-federal-trade-commission-generic-drug-entry/p052103barrierstogenericentrytestimonysenate07202006.pdf.Google Scholar
Federal Trade Commission. 2015. Brief for Amicus Curiae Federal Trade Commission Supporting Plaintiff-Appellant in Mylan Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Warner Chilcott plc, et al.. Available at www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/amicus_briefs/mylan-pharmaceuticals-inc.v.warner-chilcott-plc-et-al./151001mylanamicusbrief.pdf.Google Scholar
Golden Gate Pharmacy Services, Inc. v. Pfizer, Inc., No. 10–15978 (9th Cir. May 19, 2011).Google Scholar
Harris, Barry C., Murphy, Kevin M., Willig, Robert D., and Wright, Matthew B.. 2014. Activating Actavis: A More Complete Story. Antitrust Magazine, 28(2), 83–9.Google Scholar
Heading for the Emergency Room. 2009. The Economist, June 25. Available at www.economist.com/node/13899647.Google Scholar
Hirsh, Merrill and Dorfman, Dan Zoloth. 2005. I Didn’t Say Orphan Often: The Benefits of a Bright-Line Rule Barring Brand to Generic Payments in Hatch-Waxman Patent Settlements. Antitrust Health Care Chronicle, 19(2).Google Scholar
Lamberti, Mary J. and Getz, Kenneth. 2015. Profiles of New Approaches to Improving the Efficiency and Performance of Pharmaceutical Drug Development. Tufts Center for the Study of Drug Development White Paper. Available at http://csdd.tufts.edu/files/uploads/CSSD_PhRMAWhitePaperNEWEST.pdf.Google Scholar
Langenfeld, James. 2013. Evaluating the Size of “Reverse Payments” in Light of the Supreme Court’s Decision in FTC v. Actavis. CPI Antitrust Chronicle. Available at www.competitionpolicyinternational.com/evaluating-the-size-of-reverse-payments-in-light-of-the-supreme-court-s-decision-in-ftc-v-actavis-2/.Google Scholar
Leffler, Keith B. and Leffler, Cristofer I.. 2002. Want to Pay a Competitor to Exit the Market? Settle a Patent Infringement Case; An Argument for Per Se Condemnation of Payments by the Patent Holder. ABA Section of Antitrust Law Economics Committee Newsletter, Spring, 26–35.Google Scholar
Meijer, Inc. v. Barr Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 572 F. Supp. 2d 38 (D.C. 2008).Google Scholar
Mylan Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Warner Chilcott plc, et al. Civ. No. 12–3824 (E.D. Pa. Apr. 16, 2015).Google Scholar
National Science Foundation. 2015. Business Research and Development and Innovation: 2012. Available at www.nsf.gov/statistics/2016/nsf16301/.Google Scholar
Orszag, Jonathan. 2013. Statement of Jon Orszag Before the Committee on Senate Judiciary Subcommittee on Antitrust, Competition Policy and Consumer Rights. Available at www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/CHRG-113shrg87818.pdf.Google Scholar
Padilla, Jorge and Meunier, Valerie. 2015. Should Reverse Payment Patent Settlements Be Prohibited Per Se? Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2604071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robbins, Gary, Robbins, Aldonna, and Goodman, John. 1994. Inefficiency in the U.S. Health Care System: What Can We Do? NCPA Policy Report No. 182. Available at www.ncpa.org/pdfs/st182.pdf.Google Scholar
Schering-Plough Corp. v. FTC, 402 F.3d 1056, 1060 (11th Cir. 2005).Google Scholar
Shapiro, Carl F. 2003. Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(1), 391411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UK National Health Service. 2014. Medicines information – Licensing. Available at www.nhs.uk/conditions/Medicinesinfo/pages/safetyissues.aspx.Google Scholar
US Food and Drug Administration. 2014. “Off-Label” and Investigational Use of Marketed Drugs, Biologics, and Medical Devices – Information Sheet. Available at www.fda.gov/RegulatoryInformation/Guidances/ucm126486.htm.Google Scholar
US Food and Drug Administration. 2015. Applications for FDA Approval to Market a New Drug. Available at www.accessdata.fda.gov/scripts/cdrh/cfdocs/cfcfr/CFRSearch.cfm?CFRPart=314.Google Scholar
Vivian, Jesse C. 2008. Generic-Substitution Laws. U.S. Pharmacist. Available at www.uspharmacist.com/content/s/44/c/9787/.Google Scholar

References

Armstrong, M. 2006. Competition in Two-sided Markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 668–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, R.D. and Audretsch, D.B.. 2011. Economic Doctrines and Approaches to Antitrust. Information Technology & Innovation Foundation, Summer, 6.Google Scholar
Boliek, B. 2011. FCC Regulation Versus Antitrust: How Net Neutrality is Defining the Boundaries. Boston College Law Review, 52, 1628–9.Google Scholar
Crandall, R.W. and Jackson, C.L.. 2011. Antitrust in High-Tech Industries. Review of Industrial Organization 38(4), 319–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenach, J.A. 2012. Broadband Competition in the Internet Ecosystem. AEI Economic Studies, October, 1.Google Scholar
Evans, D. 2009. The Middle Way on Applying Antitrust to Information Technology. Competition Policy International , November (2), 2.Google Scholar
Fisher, Franklin M. 1978. Diagnosing Monopoly. Working Paper Department of Economics, MIT No. 226.Google Scholar
Hahn, Robert W., Litan, Robert E. and Singer, Hal J.. 2007. The Economics of “Wireless Net Neutrality.” AEI-Brookings Joint Center Working Paper No. RP07–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hazlett, T.W. and Weisman, D.. 2009. Market Power in U.S. Broadband Services. George Mason Law and Economic Research Paper Series 1–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hemphill, C. Scott. 2008. Network Neutrality and the False Promise of Zero-Price Regulation. Yale Journal on Regulation, 25, 135.Google Scholar
Hovenkamp, H. 2012a. Antitrust and the Movement of Technology. George Mason Law Review, 19, 1119.Google Scholar
Hovenkamp, H.J. 2012b. Antitrust and Innovation: Where We Are and Where We Should Be Going. University of Iowa Legal Studies Research Paper No. 12–03, 749.Google Scholar
Kahn, Alfred E. 2006. Telecommunications: The Transition from Regulation to Antitrust. Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law, 5, 159.Google Scholar
Katz, M.L. and Shelanski, H.A.. 2005. Schumpeterian Competition and Antitrust Policy in High Tech Markets. Competition, 7, 4.Google Scholar
Manne, G.A. and Wright, J.D.. 2010. Innovation and the Limits of Antitrust. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 6(1), 156–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nuechterlein, Jonathan E. 2009. Antitrust Oversight of an Antitrust Debate: An Institutional Perspective on the Net Neutrality Debate. Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law, 7, 19.Google Scholar
Owen, B.M. 2011. Antitrust and Vertical Integration in “New Economy” Industries with Application to Broadband Access. Review of Industrial Organization 38(4), 363–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parker, G.G. and Alstyne, M.W.. 2005. Two-Sided Network Effects: A Theory of Information Product Design. Management Science, 51(10), 1494–504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasquale, Frank. 2010. Beyond Innovation and Competition: The Need for Qualified Transparency in Internet Intermediaries. Northwestern University Law Review, 104, 105.Google Scholar
Prieger, James E., Molnar, Gabor, and Savage, Scott J.. 2014. Quality Competition in the Broadband Service Provision Industry. Paper presented at 2014 TPRC/42nd Research Conference on Communication, Information and Internet Policy.Google Scholar
Rysman, M. 2009. The Economics of Two-Sided Markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(3), 125–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, C. 1999. Exclusivity in Network Industries. George Mason Law Review, 7, 673.Google Scholar
Shelanski, H.A. 2007. Adjusting Regulation to Competition: Toward a New Model for U.S. Telecommunications Policy. Yale Law Journal on Regulation, 24, 57.Google Scholar
Spulber, D.F. and Yoo, C.S.. 2007. Mandating Access to Telecom and the Internet: The Hidden Side of Trinko. Columbia Law Review, 107.Google Scholar
Yoo, C. 2005. Beyond Network Neutrality. Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, 19, 17.Google Scholar
Yoo, C.S. 2006. Network Neutrality and the Economics of Congestion. Georgetown Law Journal, 94, 1851–2.Google Scholar

References

Brooks, Roger and Geradin, Damien. 2011. Taking Contracts Seriously: The Meaning of the Voluntary Commitment to License Essential Patents on “Fair and Reasonable” Terms. In Anderman, S. and Ezrachi, A. (eds.), Intellectual Property and Competition Law: New Frontiers. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Carlton, Dennis W. and Shampine, Allan L.. 2014. Identifying Benchmarks for Applying Non-Discrimination in FRAND. Competition Policy International Chronicle, 1, 2.Google Scholar
Chien, Colleen. 2014. “Holding up” and “Holding Out”. Michigan Telecommunications & Technology Law Review, 21, 1.Google Scholar
Contreras, Jorge. 2015. Market Reliance and Patent Pledges. Utah Law Review, 2.Google Scholar
Cournot, Augustin. 1838. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth. Bacon, Nathaniel T. trans. New York: Macmillan (1987).Google Scholar
CSIRO v. Cisco. Federal Circuit. December 1, 2015.Google Scholar
Department of Justice. 2006. Letter from Assistant Attorney General Thomas O. Barnett to Robert A. Skitol, October 30. Available at www.justice.gov/atr/response-vmebus-international-trade-association-vitas-request-business-review-letter.Google Scholar
Department of Justice. 2015. Letter from Acting Assistant Attorney General Renata B. Hesse to Michael A. Lindsay, February 2. Available at www.justice.gov/atr/response-institute-electrical-and-electronics-engineers-incorporated.Google Scholar
Department of Justice and U.S. Patent Office. 2013. Policy Statement on Remedies For Standards-Essential Patents Subject To Voluntary F/Rand Commitments. Available at www.uspto.gov/about/offices/ogc/Final_DOJ-PTO_Policy_Statement_on_FRAND_SEPs_1-8-13.pdf.Google Scholar
Elhauge, Einer. 2008. Do Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking Lead to Systematically Excessive Royalties? Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 4, 535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elhauge, Einer. 2015. Treating RAND Commitments Neutrally. Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 11, 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ericsson v. D-Link, 773 F.3d 1201 (Fed. Cir. 2014).Google Scholar
Ewing, Tom. 2011. Indirect Exploitation of Intellectual Property Rights By Corporations and Investors. Hastings Science & Technology Law Journal, 4.Google Scholar
FTC. 2007. Opinion of the Commission on Remedy in the Matter of Rambus Inc. by Chairman Deborah Platt Majoras.Google Scholar
Farrell, Joseph and Katz, Michael. 2005. Competition or Predation? Consumer Coordination, Strategic Pricing and Price Floors in Network Markets. Journal of Industrial Economics, 53(2), 203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, Joseph, Hayes, John, Shapiro, Carl, and Sullivan, Catherine. 2007. Standard Setting, Patents, and Hold-Up. Antitrust Law Journal, 74, 603.Google Scholar
Galetovic, Alexander, Haber, Stephen, and Levine, Ross. 2015. An Empirical Examination of Patent Holdup. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 11(3), 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116, 1120 (S.D.N.Y.) 1970.Google Scholar
Geradin, Damien. 2010. Reverse Hold-ups: The (Often Ignored) Risks Faced by Innovators in Standardized Areas. The Pros and Cons of Standard Setting 2010. Swedish Competition Authority.Google Scholar
Geradin, Damien. 2014. The Meaning of “Fair and Reasonable” in the Context of Third-Party Determination of FRAND Terms. George Mason Law Review, 21, 919.Google Scholar
Geradin, Damien and Layne-Farrar, Anne. 2007. The Logic and Limits of Ex Ante Competition in a Standard-Setting Environment. Competition Policy International, 3(1).Google Scholar
Geradin, Damien, Layne-Farrar, Anne, and Padilla, Jorge. 2008. The Ex Ante Auction Model for the Control of Market Power in Standard Setting Organizations. European Competition Journal, 4(8).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geradin, Damien, Layne-Farrar, Anne, and Padilla, Jorge. 2011. Elves or Trolls? The Role of Nonpracticing Patent Owners in the Innovation Economy. Industrial and Corporate Change, June, 1.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Richard. 2011. Deal or No Deal? Licensing Negotiations by Standard Setting Organizations. Antitrust Law Journal, 77, 855.Google Scholar
Golden, John. 2007. Commentary: “Patent Trolls” and Patent Remedies. Texas Law Review, 85, 2111.Google Scholar
Harkrider, John. 2013. REPs Not SEPs: A Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory Approach to Licensing Commitments. Antitrust Chronicle, 10.Google Scholar
Kieff, F. Scott and Layne-Farrar, Anne. 2013. Incentive Effects from Different Approaches to Holdup Mitigation Surrounding Patent Remedies and Standard-Setting Organizations. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 9(4), 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Larouche, Pierre, Padilla, Jorge, and Taffet, Richard. 2014. Settling FRAND Disputes: Is Mandatory Arbitration a Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory Alternative? Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 10, 581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne. 2010. Nondiscriminatory Pricing: Is Standard Setting Different? Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 6(4), 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne. 2011. Innovative or Indefensible? An Empirical Assessment of Patenting within Standard Setting. International Journal of IT Standards and Standardization Research, 9, 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne. 2014. Moving Past the SEP RAND Obsession: Some Thoughts on the Economic Implications of Unilateral Commitments and the Complexities of Patent Licensing. George Mason Law Review, 21.Google Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne and Llobet, Gerard. 2014. Moving Beyond Simple Examples: Assessing the Incremental Value Rule within Standards. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 36, 57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne and Wong-Ervin, Koren. 2015. An Analysis of the Federal Circuit’s Decision in Ericsson v. D-Link. CPI Antitrust Chronicle, March.Google Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne, Llobet, Gerard, and Padilla, Jorge. 2014a. Payments and Participation: The Incentives to Join Cooperative Standard Setting Efforts. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 23, 2449.Google Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne, Llobet, Gerard, and Padilla, Jorge. 2014b. Patent Licensing in Vertically Disaggregated Industries: The Royalty Allocation Neutrality Principle. Communications and Strategies 5.Google Scholar
Layne-Farrar, Anne, Padilla, Jorge, and Schmalensee, Richard. 2007. Pricing Patents for Licensing in Standard Setting Organizations: Making Sense of FRAND Commitments. Antitrust Law Journal, 74, 671.Google Scholar
Lemley, Mark and Melamed, Douglas. 2013. Missing the Forest for the Trolls. Columbia Law Review, 113, 2117.Google Scholar
Lemley, Mark and Shapiro, Carl. 2007. Patent Holdup and Royalty Stacking. Texas Law Review, 85, 1989.Google Scholar
Lemley, Mark and Shapiro, Carl. 2013. A Simple Approach to Setting Reasonable Royalties for Standard-Essential Patents. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 28, 1135.Google Scholar
Lerner, Joshua and Tirole, Jean. 2015. Restoring Competition in Standard-essential Patents. Journal of Political Economy, 123(3), 547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lloyd, Andrew. 2015. Ericsson and Nokia the latest to confirm that they will not license under the new IEEE patent policy. IAM, blog. Available at www.iam-media.com/Blog/Detail.aspx?g=d07d0bde-ebd6-495a-aa72-4eecb9dac67d.Google Scholar
Mariniello, Mario. 2011. Fair, Reasonable and Non-Discriminatory (FRAND) Terms: A Challenge for Competition Authorities. Journal of Competition Law & Economics, 7, 523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Microsoft v. Motorola. 2012. Federal Circuit. 696 F.3d 872 (9th Cir.).Google Scholar
Microsoft v. Motorola. 2013. Federal Circuit. Case No. C10-1823JLR.Google Scholar
Miller, Joseph Scott. 2006. Standard Setting, Patents, and Access Lock-In: RAND Licensing and the Theory of the Firm. Indiana Law Review, 40.Google Scholar
Mintzer, Erica and Munck, Suzanne. 2014. The Joint U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Patent Assertion Entity Activities – “Follow The Money.” Antitrust Law Journal, 79, 423.Google Scholar
Ohana, Gil, Hansen, Marc and Shah, Omar. 2003. Disclosure and Negotiation of Licensing Terms Prior to Adoption of Industry Standards: Preventing Another Patent Ambush. European Competition Law Review, 24, 644.Google Scholar
Rambus v. FTC. 2008. 522 F.3d 456 Nos. 07-1086, 07-1124. United States Court of Appeals, District of Columbia Circuit.Google Scholar
Realtek v. LSI. 2014. District Court, Northern District of California. Case No. C-12-3451-RMW.Google Scholar
Rysman, Marc and Simcoe, Tim. 2008. Patents and the Performance of Voluntary Standard-Setting Organizations. Management Science, 54(11), 1920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott Morton, Fiona and Shapiro, Carl. 2014. Strategic Patent Acquisitions. Antitrust Law Journal, 79(2) 463.Google Scholar
Scott Morton, Fiona and Shapiro, Carl. 2015. Patent Assertions: Are We Any Closer to Aligning Reward to Contribution? NBER Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Carl. 2001. Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard-Setting. In Jaffe, Adam, Lerner, Joshua, and Stern, Scott (eds.), Innovation Policy and the Economy, Vol. I. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Swanson, D. and Baumol, W.. 2005. Reasonable and Nondiscriminatory (RAND) Royalties, Standards Selection, and the Control of Market Power. Antitrust Law Journal, 73, 727.Google Scholar
VirnetX, Inc. and Science Applications International Corporation v. Cisco Systems, Inc. and Apple Inc. 2014. Court of Appeals of the Federal Circuit.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×