Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 July 2014
When property rights to valuable environmental and natural resources exist, there are many potential benefits. It is possible to restrict competitive entry to avoid the losses of open access, to encourage long-term investment in the resource (including conservation), to promote exchange, which can channel the resource to higher-valued uses, and to avoid wasteful and potentially divisive conflict that occurs when valuable resources are open to all. Property rights – common and private – are useful as alternatives to government regulation for many environmental and natural resource problems. They may be the low-cost option, relative to regulation or tax policies, and they may better align users’ incentives with conservation or other mitigation goals.
Even with these advantages, property rights often are resorted to late in resource use after many of the rents have been dissipated from excessive exploitation. For example, in 1973, fishery economist Francis Christy called for the use of individual transferable quotas (ITQs) as property rights to the right to fish within an overall total allowable catch (TAC) to avoid overfishing. Serious adoption of ITQs did not occur for some 20 years when they were put into place in Iceland and New Zealand. Similarly, the notion of tradable emission permits as property rights to reduce air pollution was put forward by Thomas Crocker in 1966 and by J.H. Dales in 1968, but their adoption also took another 30 years. Further, when property rights are adopted, they often are limited. ITQs and emission permits in the United States are not legal property rights subject to takings protection, but use rights, subject to reassignment or termination by the government. Trading in ITQs is restricted to certain parties and the quantity of quotas that can be held. These limitations on property rights reduce the ability of environmental markets to more fully address the losses of the common pool. The question is why? In this chapter, we explore the political economy of property rights.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.