Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T11:37:16.886Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Individual Sovereignty and Coproduction of Knowledge Governance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 December 2021

Erwin Dekker
Affiliation:
Mercatus Center, George Mason University, Virginia
Pavel Kuchař
Affiliation:
King's College London
Get access

Summary

Common pooling of knowledge goods requires effective governance institutions to avoid over depletion or under provision. Following recent literature, this chapter treats the institutions of knowledge goods governance as dually coproduced in provision and common pool in consumption. I combine a notion of individual sovereignty from political economy with a scalar analysis of the knowledge content of goods exchanged within a community. Insofar as the economic value of goods depends on knowledge content, and less on physical expression, exchange acts are speech acts. Therefore, communities where individuals have high exchange rights also feature a high form of speech rights. In these contexts, agents contribute to governance as an outcome of their ordinary economic activity. Therefore, entrepreneurship within rules and entrepreneurship to alter rules are not distinct actions. The paper relies on a combination of constitutive and regulative rules within a community, as defined by economic and social rather than geographic or political boundaries. Individuals use sovereign exchange and speech acts to interact within given rules, and in doing so they also contribute to the coproduction of governance, acting at once as both economic and institutional entrepreneurs.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aligica, Paul D., Boettke, Peter J., and Tarko, Vlad. 2019. Public Governance and the Classical-Liberal Perspective. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce. 2005. “The Mythology of Holdout as a Justification for Eminent Domain and Public Provision of Roads.” The Independent Review 10 (2): 165194.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter J., and Candela, Rosolino. 2017. “The Liberty of Progress: Increasing Returns, Institutions, and Entrepreneurship.” Social Philosophy and Policy 34 (2): 136163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1965. “An Economic Theory of Clubs.” Economica 32 (125): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1975. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1996. “Federalism and Individual Sovereignty.” Cato Journal 15 (2–3): 259268.Google Scholar
Caton, James, and López, Edward J.. 2020. “The Cognitive Dimension of Institutions.” In A Companion to Douglass North, edited by Marroquín, Andres and Wenzel, Nikolai, 233260. Francisco Marroquín University.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald. 1959. “The Federal Communications Commission.” Journal of Law & Economics 2: 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cole, Daniel H., and Grossman, Peter Z.. 2005. Principles of Law and Economics. Pearson Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Crawford, Susan, and Ostrom, Elinor. 1995. “A Grammar of Institutions.” American Political Science Review 89 (3): 582600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunningham, Emily. 2009. “Protecting Cuisine under the Rubric of Intellectual Property Law: Should the Law Play a Bigger Role in the Kitchen?Journal of High Technology Law 9: 2151.Google Scholar
de Jouvenel, Bertrand. 1957 [1997]. Sovereignty: An Inquiry into the Political Good. Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Dedeurwaerdere, Tom, Frischmann, Brett, Hess, Charlotte, Lametti, David, Madison, Michael, Schweik, Charles, and Strandburg, Katherine. 2014. “An Introduction to Knowledge Commons.” Workshop on Governing Knowledge Commons.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1994. Order without Law. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, David. 2000. Law’s Order: What Economics Has to Do with Law and Why It Matters. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Frischmann, Brett M. 2012. Infrastructure: The Social Value of Shared Resources. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frischmann, Brett M., Marciano, Alain, and Ramello, Giovanni Battista. 2019. “Tragedy of the Commons after 50 Years.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33 (4): 211228.Google Scholar
Frischmann, Brett M., Madison, Michael J., and Strandburg, Jatherine J. (eds.). 2014. Governing Knowledge Commons. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Harris, Colin. 2018. “Institutional Solutions to Free-Riding in Peer-to-Peer Networks: A Case Study of Online Pirate Communities.” Journal of Institutional Economics 14 (5): 901924.Google Scholar
Hazlett, Thomas W. 2017. The Political Spectrum: The Tumultuous Liberation of Wireless Technology, from Herbert Hoover to the Smartphone. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hess, Charlotte, and Ostrom, Elinor. 2007. Understanding Knowledge as Commons. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hess, Charlotte, and Ostrom, Elinor. 2014. “Modeling Science as a Contribution Good.” Research Policy 43: 10141024.Google Scholar
Landes, William M., and Posner, Richard A.. 2002. “Indefinitely Renewable Copyright.” John M. Olin Law & Economics Working Paper No. 154: 148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Peter. 2008. “Social Distance and Self-Enforcing Exchange.” Journal of Legal Studies 37: 161188.Google Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence. 2003. “Dunwody Distinguished Lecture in Law: The Creative Commons.” Florida Law Review 55 (3): 763768.Google Scholar
Loshin, Jacob. 2010. “Secrets Revealed: Protecting Magicians’ Intellectual Property without Law.” In Law and Magic: A Collection of Essays, edited by Christine A., Corcos, pp. 123142. Durham: Carolina Academic Press.Google Scholar
Miceli, Thomas. 2014. The Economic Theory of Eminent Domain: Private Property, Public Use. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1983. “The Elements of an Action Situation.” Working Paper W83–23. Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Bloomington, IN.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1985. “Formulating the Elements of Institutional Analysis.” Working Paper W85–15. Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Bloomington, IN.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1999. “Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms.” Working Paper W99–20. Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Bloomington, IN.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2005. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2010. “Prize Lecture: Beyond Markets and States – Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems.” American Economic Review 100 (June): 641672.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Vincent. 2006. “The 2005 John Gaus Lecture: Citizen-Sovereigns – The Source of Contestability, the Rule of Law, and the Conduct of Public Entrepreneurship.” PS: Political Science and Politics 39 (1): 1317.Google Scholar
Philpott, Daniel. 2016. “Sovereignty.” Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2016): 1–24, https://plato.stanford.edu/cgi-bin/encyclopedia/archinfo.cgi?entry=sovereignty.Google Scholar
Raustiala, Kal, and Sprigman, Chris. 2006. “The Piracy Paradox: Innovation and Intellectual Property in Fashion Design.” Virginia Law Review 92 (8): 16881777.Google Scholar
Schmitt, Carl. 1934 [2005]. Political Theology, Four Chapters on the Concept of Sovereignty. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Searle, John R. 1995. The Construction of Social Reality. The Free Press.Google Scholar
Searle, John R. 2006. “Social Ontology: Some Basic Principles.” Anthropological Theory 6 (1): 1229.Google Scholar
Tao, Jin, Ho, Chun-Yu, Luo, Shougui, and Sheng, Yue. 2019. “Agglomeration Economies in Creative Industries.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 77: 141154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Tocqueville, Alexis. [1835, 1840] 1945. Democracy in America, edited by Bradley, Phillips, 2 vols. Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×