Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T04:22:41.196Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - The Unequal Geographical Distribution of Innovative Activity

Implications for Income Inequality and Innovation Policies*

from Part I - Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Issues

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2024

Daniel Benoliel
Affiliation:
University of Haifa, Israel
Peter K. Yu
Affiliation:
Texas A & M University School of Law
Francis Gurry
Affiliation:
World Intellectual Property Organization
Keun Lee
Affiliation:
Seoul National University

Summary

Innovation is at the core of economic development, growth, and structural change. Yet, it does not spur in nor flow to all corners of the world. This chapter reviews and describes empirically the uneven geographical distribution of innovation and its dynamics, at both the national and subnational levels. It also compares such distribution in relation to other indicators of economic activity. The chapter then examines the potential consequences of such unequal distribution, particularly for its possible influence on inter-regional income inequality, and discusses how inevitable they might be. In light of available evidence, it explores what the role of policy could be.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Introduction

Innovation is at the core of economic development, growth, and structural change. This has been well demonstrated previously by scholars both theoretically and empirically (WIPO, 2015). Yet, it does not spur in nor flow to all corners of the world. Not all countries innovate at the same rate; within these, not all regions either. Not even in the most innovative countries is innovation equally distributed or seamlessly flows from national championing areas to the rest of the country.

To a great extent, such unequal innovation distribution mirrors the continuing wide differences in per capita incomes across and within different countries (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019). Indeed, many economists argue that differences in technology diffusion go a long way in explaining income differences (e.g., Comin and Mestieri, Reference Comin and Mestieri2018). Worldwide rankings of innovation and income per capita are, however, not necessarily written in stone. Some Asian countries – and several regions within these – were able to achieve remarkable industrial development during the past forty years. Today these regions host companies that compete at the world’s technology frontier.

How has this unequal distribution of innovation evolved across and within countries? Does innovation concentrate more than other economic activities? What are the consequences of this concentration for territorial income inequality? Can policy actions do something about this? We aim to answer these questions using patent and publication data for more than forty years, and reviewing the relevant literature.

Understanding where most of innovation happens across and within countries is of foremost importance for innovation and intellectual property (IP) policymaking. Reviewing the successful technological trajectories and the less successful ones can be informative of the paths to follow. A natural question to ask is what role public policies can play in changing the technological trajectory of countries and regions. Given the many market failures associated with knowledge acquisition and knowledge diffusion, it is also pertinent to ponder what IP policy can do specifically.

This chapter is divided into two main sections. The first section reviews and describes empirically the uneven geographical distribution of innovation and its dynamics, at both the national and subnational levels. It also compares such distribution in relation to other indicators of economic activity. The second section examines the potential consequences of such unequal distribution, particularly for its possible influence on inter-regional income inequality, and discusses how inevitable they might be. In light of available evidence, it explores what the role of policy could be.

2.1 Innovation’s Uneven Geographical Distribution

During much of the past century, knowledge was produced mostly in a few wealthy countries, in particular the United States, Japan, and some Western European economies. What is often much less appreciated is how concentrated this phenomenon is, even within these wealthy nations.Footnote 1

The academic literature has investigated several reasons behind such concentration. Many have to do with the virtuous cycle of national innovation systems (NIS) (Edquist, Reference Edquist and Edquist1997) and, within these, the cycles of the local innovation ecosystems (Asheim and Gertler, Reference Asheim, Gertler, Fagerberg and Mowery2005). Long and stable positive economic cycles explain how the best higher-education and research institutions appear and consolidate in certain regions of the world. The same applies to the private sector, where research- and technology-intensive companies flourish in such conditions. The reverse causality also applies: The liveliest NIS of today are more likely to spur innovation and consequent economic growth of tomorrow. For many reasons, these research and development (R&D) intensive companies will prefer to perform their research operations and collaborate with knowledge-intensive partners close to their headquarters (Castellacci and Archibugi, Reference Castellacci and Archibugi2008; Chaminade et al., Reference Chaminade, De Fuentes, Harirchi, Plechero, Shearmur, Doloreux and Carrincazeaux2016; Patel and Pavitt, Reference Patel and Pavitt1991). The two directions of causality can generate virtuous and vicious cycles, perpetuating the differences across economies.

National interactions are only part of the successful cycles, the other part being the interactions within the network of successful locations (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019; WIPO, 2019: ch. 1). It is often argued that the concentration of innovation production can be compensated with a spread of knowledge flows in all directions. Advocates of knowledge spillovers and knowledge as a public good would argue that knowledge diffuses from the innovation production center to the less innovative neighboring countries and regions. However, there is a known imperfect diffusion of knowledge, as information does not diffuse as freely or as fast everywhere, nor is the ability to fully exploit information flows – that is, the absorptive capacity – equally distributed around the world.Footnote 2 In this sense, the choice of knowledge connections is affected by the aforementioned virtuous cycles – that is, both economic and innovative – in each of the potential locations. The motivations for these connections can be of various nature: Multinational companies (MNCs) seek knowledge strategically (Castellani and Zanfei, Reference Castellani and Zanfei2006, Reference Castellani and Zanfei2007); supply and value chains reshape their structure globally (Bathelt et al., Reference Bathelt, Malmberg and Maskell2004; Dunning, Reference Dunning1998); decentralized interpersonal networks shine where there is professional talent (Lorenzen and Mudambi, Reference Lorenzen and Mudambi2013); and scientists, innovators, and entrepreneurs move where there are economic and innovation opportunities (Breschi et al., Reference Breschi, Lissoni and Miguelez2017; Franzoni et al., Reference Franzoni, Scellato and Stephan2012; Saxenian, Reference Saxenian2002, Reference Saxenian2006). Chaminade et al. (Reference Chaminade, De Fuentes, Harirchi, Plechero, Shearmur, Doloreux and Carrincazeaux2016) summarize these different interactions as global innovation networks (GINs) aiming to collectively produce and disseminate new knowledge.Footnote 3

Undoubtedly, innovation eventually diffuses to less innovative regions and countries (Comin and Mestieri, Reference Comin and Mestieri2018). But the rate at which innovation flows from and to a country might be very different depending on the country’s position in the GINs. Successful companies in equally successful countries are also likely to increase their multinational activity overseas, but these countries may also attract other foreign companies. Indeed, it is not surprising that the majority of the MNCs have either spawned in the United States, Japan, or Western Europe or moved their headquarters there. Over the past century, these MNCs have increasingly operated in foreign countries and, lately, have increased their international R&D operations and the geographical diversity of their locations. Yet, many scholars argue that technology transfer to foreign economies – especially developing ones – is imperfect. Most of MNC’s overseas R&D activities in developing economies before the turn of the century were confined to market adaptation, with limited production of new knowledge (Gerybadze and Merk, Reference Gerybadze and Merk2014; Krishna et al., Reference Krishna, Patra and Bhattacharya2012).

Was this virtuous cycle unattainable for the rest of the world? The pattern over the past thirty years has shown us otherwise. The last part of the past century and the early years of the twenty-first century display several East Asian and other economies emerging as innovation hubs (Branstetter et al., Reference Branstetter, Li, Veloso, Jaffe and Jones2014). Several factors explain this rise. MNCs increasingly redirect foreign investment to gain access to specialized knowledge (Amendolagine et al., Reference Amendolagine, Chaminade, Guimón, Rabellotti, Taubman and Watal2019; Reddy, Reference Reddy1997). High-skilled professionals and talented entrepreneurs coming from these areas move and connect across the globe, building unprecedented international knowledge pipelines (Foley and Kerr, Reference Foley and Kerr2013; Saxenian, Reference Saxenian2006; Useche et al., Reference Useche, Miguelez and Lissoni2020). As a result, China, India, and some other economies have created over that period the environment not only to induce inward R&D activities by MNCs but also to spawn their own local stakeholders (Awate et al., Reference Awate, Larsen and Mudambi2012; Branstetter et al., Reference Branstetter, Li, Veloso, Jaffe and Jones2014).Footnote 4 Analyzing the early technological developments of Chinese clusters, Zhou and Xin (Reference Zhou and Xin2003) found that local firms in tech clusters benefit from collaborating with MNCs, which provides them with vital technology and organizational training, in turn vastly increasing their innovative capacity.

In the following paragraphs, we make use of patent and scientific publication data to describe empirically the patterns and trends portrayed in the innovation literature earlier. We use scientific publication data from Clarivate’s Web of Science (WoS) and Science Citation Index Expanded (SCIE), and patent data from EPO’s Patstat, World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), and other patent data sources.Footnote 5

2.1.1 A Slow Pattern of Knowledge Internationalization?

For the past decades, only three economies – namely the United States, Japan, and Germany – accounted for the majority of scientific and technological (S&T) production (Figure 2.1). Within these two indicators, patents’ concentration is always more geographically skewed than scientific articles. Simply adding France, Italy, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom increases the concentration of patents during the second half of the past century to roughly 90 percent.

Source: Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019). Notes: RoW = Rest of the World. See WIPO (2019), technical notes (www.wipo.int/wipr)

Figure 2.1 Evolution of (a) patenting and (b) scientific publication concentration by few economies.

These data also show that the distribution of new S&T outputs changed by the turn of the century. The growth of the Republic of Korea and China – but also the other economies grouped as a whole – has outperformed that of the United States, Japan, and Western European countries as a block. Outside of China and the Republic of Korea, fastest innovation economies are also found in Asia. In particular, India, Iran, Israel, Singapore, and Turkey stand out. The geographical spread is more noticeable in scientific outputs than technological ones. In the rest of the world, Australia, Brazil, Egypt, and South Africa gather the lion’s share of the scientific output in their respective regions. However, virtually all nontraditional regions evidence an increase in the scientific output share.

There has been, therefore, some spreading out of knowledge production. However, except for the Republic of Korea first and then China, the hierarchy of innovativeness (and income per capita) has not changed to a great extent (Kemeny, Reference Kemeny2011), as high-income countries have managed to keep their positions through sustained innovation, and innovation of higher quality and complexity (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019). Moreover, the entry of these new players has not necessarily translated into a reduction of geographical concentration. Indeed, among other factors, the extremely rapid emergence of a few countries, notably the Republic of Korea and China, had recently resulted in a reconcentration phenomenon (see Figure 2.2).

Figure 2.2 Innovation is more concentrated than other economic activities

Herfindahl–Hirschman index, selected innovation and economic indicators, 1980–2016.

Source: Authors based on PATSTAT, PCT, and Web of Science data. R&D and R&D personnel are retrieved from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics, while exports and GDP data from the World Development Indicators, the World Bank.

By all quantitative accounts, the production of innovation remains more concentrated than other economic activities. At the country level, this is quite apparent. Figure 2.2 reports the country concentration index – Herfindahl–Hirschman Index – for a series of internationally comparable economic indicators over time. In addition to the scientific articles and international patents already discussed in the previous section, this figure also presents indicators for trade (total exports, U.S. dollars PPP), GDP (U.S. dollars PPP), R&D investments (GERD, U.S. dollars PPP), R&D personnel (FTE), and population.

These indicators suggest quite clearly that innovation-related activities are geographically more concentrated than economic ones, such as trade and GDP. The concentration of scientific articles has been declining close to the levels observed for the concentration of GDP. By contrast, R&D expenditures have observed an increase in concentration similar to that for patents since the mid-2000s. The fact that R&D investments are more concentrated than R&D personnel implicitly indicates that R&D budgets per researcher differ substantially across countries. Typically, R&D in richer countries is far more capital intensive, which translates into higher R&D labor productivity. This is in line with the differences in innovation output concentration and also their quality.Footnote 6

What do the data tell us about S&T collaboration? The broad context is that the overall S&T collaboration – that is, local, national, and international altogether – is increasing. Within this increase in collaboration, the share of international scientific collaboration has also been steadily rising (WIPO, 2019). On the contrary, the share of international technological collaboration – as measured in international coinventions – exhibits a substantially lower and less stable pattern. Peaking at almost 11 percent in the 2000s, the share of international coinventorship came a long way from low single digits in the 1970s. Since the 2010s, however, the share of international coinventorship has plateaued and, lately, decreased – mostly explained by the declines in international coinventorship observed in the United States, China, France, and India.

Does knowledge flow globally? The majority of international S&T collaborations occur between and within the United States and Western Europe. The rest of the world is increasingly collaborating internationally, but when it does, it almost always selects a partner from the United States or Western Europe. Interestingly, both international S&T collaboration between other countries – that is, outside the United States and Western Europe – has been increasing for the last two decades but remains small in comparison. In the period 2011–2015, Western Europe gathered 49 percent and 41 percent of all international S&T collaboration, respectively. In the same period, the United States gathered 13 percent and 27 percent for the same indicators (WIPO, 2019). Nevertheless, over the years, the U.S. connections with China and India have become equally or more important than those between the United States and individual Western European countries. This is particularly the case for international coinventorships. Despite being quite advanced, established non-Western economies such as Japan, the Republic of Korea, and Australia, and emerging economies such as China, India, Singapore, and Brazil mostly collaborate with the United States and Western Europe. In sum, while collaboration in S&T has increased and, in turn, has contributed to knowledge diffusion – especially from more to less developed countries – it remains quite skewed, and the number of emerging countries entering the global network is still limited.

2.1.2 Within Countries, Innovation Is Unevenly Localized in a Few Regions

Be it in the traditional technologically leading countries, or the newly emerged ones, knowledge production does not take place in a spatial vacuum. The multiple sources of knowledge behind the invention, commercialization, and adoption of new products, processes, services, and social practices originate in specific locations within countries and diffuse unevenly across them.

In particular, as most economic activities, innovation benefits from economies of agglomeration (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019; WIPO, 2019: ch. 1). Scientists, technologists, entrepreneurs, students, and other actors seeking ideas, expertise, and education realize gains when they are colocated, as this increases the probability of recognizing opportunities and solving problems and of lowering all types of search costs. Innovation generated in large agglomerations tends to be of higher quality and more unconventional (Berkes and Gaetani, Reference Berkes and Gaetani2021). Firms, especially innovation-centered ones, are inevitably attracted to innovation clusters by the possibility to access a large and diverse supply of labor (especially labor markets for qualified workers) and of intermediate goods (especially knowledge-intensive ones) but also by the faster flow of ideas.Footnote 7 They also allow interacting and learning from peers, favoring localized knowledge spillovers (LKS) (Jaffe et al., Reference Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson1993). Agglomerations are homes and hosts of multinational enterprises (MNEs) and the true beneficiaries of globalization, being centers of political influence, corporate decision-making and control, knowledge generation and exchange, skills, and jobs (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019; Feldman et al., Reference Feldman, Guy and Iammarino2021). Similarly, skilled workers, students, and entrepreneurs looking for jobs, knowledge, and business opportunities move to the same centers, giving rise to nonnegligible internal and international migration flows (Breschi et al., Reference Breschi, Lawson, Lissoni, Morrison and Salter2020). Thus, the typical innovative urban agglomeration relies heavily on the external knowledge flows channeled from the national system of innovation, the local MNC’s headquarters or subsidiaries, the international science networks, and the mobility of talented people and skilled workers (Bathelt et al., Reference Bathelt, Malmberg and Maskell2004; Lorenzen and Mudambi, Reference Lorenzen and Mudambi2013; Moreno and Miguélez, Reference Moreno and Miguélez2012).Footnote 8

While both the economic and geography literatures stress the importance of agglomerations for innovative activities, their identification remains an open challenge. At the beginning of the past century, Alfred Marshall already discussed why industries agglomerate and defined the industries concentrating in Birmingham, Bedfordshire, Buckinghamshire, Manchester, or Sheffield as districts (Marshall, Reference Marshall and Abridged1920). More recently, scholars have argued that innovation flourishes in dense urban areas, where knowledge spillovers can flow within and across industries (Glaeser et al., Reference Glaeser, Kallal, Scheinkman and Shleifer1992; Jacobs, Reference Jacobs1969; Porter, Reference Porter2000). Indeed, several Marshallian districts can coexist and benefit each other in an innovative large metropolitan area. These global innovation hotspots spawn new ideas and technologies faster than other locations, thanks to the agglomeration of capital, skills, entrepreneurship, and the supporting scientific institutions (Engel, Reference Engel2015; Engel and del-Palacio, Reference Engel and del-Palacio2009; WIPO, 2019: ch. 1). Porter (Reference Porter2000) defines as clusters the spatial units that concentrate geographically and thematically a whole series of private and public organizations – and the people therein – that compete and cooperate to achieve innovation. Other terminology ranges from “tech clusters” (when wishing to stress their peculiarities vis-à-vis industrial clusters; Kerr and Robert-Nicoud, Reference Kerr and Robert-Nicoud2020) to “innovation hubs” (where the emphasis is placed on cities and knowledge exchanges between them; Nijkamp and Kourtit, Reference Nijkamp and Kourtit2013) as well as “hotspots,” which is more neutral and used interchangeably with the former two. Other approaches, instead, identify “global cities” based on their population and economic activity, and then move on to quantify the innovation they produce (Barca et al., Reference Barca, McCann and Rodríguez‐Pose2012; Castellani, Reference Castellani, Cook, Johns, McDonald, Beaverstock and Pandit2018).

Figure 12 by Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019) shows the global distribution of international patents and scientific articles by the smallest available administrative area within each country. We observe instantly in this figure that both S&T outputs are sternly skewed to a few locations in the world. Not surprisingly, these locations are mostly confined to the same regions we have been discussing earlier, namely the United States, Western Europe, and East Asia. Within the United States, the main cities on the two coasts – such as Boston, New York, and San Francisco – stand out. In East Asia, Beijing, Seoul, Shanghai, Shenzhen, and Tokyo are among the densest S&T agglomerations. Western Europe shows a more uniform geographical distribution, yet cities in France, Germany, Northern Italy, and the United Kingdom agglomerate more S&T outputs.

Yet, using administrative areas for worldwide analysis is problematic. Efforts to map innovation agglomerations, especially at the international level, should not rely on fixed spatial boundaries, such as administrative or political units (Carlino and Kerr, Reference Carlino, Kerr, Duranton, Henderson and Strange2015). This practice suffers from both a “modifiable area unit problem” (the unit size may vary across countries, thus making quantitative comparisons impossible) and a “border effect” problem (the unit boundaries may either cut across a cross-border agglomeration or – in case of large units – include two distinct agglomerations).Footnote 9 In this chapter, we will adopt the term “innovation-dense areas,” which will be proxied by the spatial boundaries computed in Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019) and WIPO (2019). In a nutshell, based on the coordinates assigned to each patent and publication (based on inventors’ and scientists’ addresses), the authors apply a clustering algorithm to identify a multitude of agglomerations worldwide. These are separately identified as “global innovation hotspots” (GIHs) and “niche clusters” (NCs), though for simplicity we analyze them together under the label innovation-dense areas.

According to WIPO (2019), the United States hosts most of the main innovation-dense areas of the world (25 percent of all), followed by Germany (12.9 percent), Japan (9.4 percent), China (6.8 percent), the United Kingdom (4.9 percent), and France (4.3 percent).Footnote 10 By continent, Europe concentrates 40.5 percent of the most innovation-dense areas, followed by North America (28 percent), Asia (25 percent), Latin America (2.9 percent), Oceania (2.7 percent), and Africa (1 percent).

Figure 2.3 depicts the share of patents and publications produced in the innovation-dense areas of the United States, Japan, Germany, the United Kingdom, the Republic of Korea, China, India, and Brazil, and the population residing in these countries. Several patterns arise from analyzing the innovation-dense areas of these countries. First, in all cases, they account for a disproportionate amount of the S&T output with respect to population. Clearly, in all countries shown here, science and innovation are substantially more concentrated than population, indicating that concentration of population only partially explains the geographical concentration of innovation. Second, the most valuable S&T output – as proxied by the top ten cited patents and publications – is typically more concentrated than the rest. Third, in general, the concentration trends are stable over time. However, we observe some increases in subnational concentration in Figure 2.3. Such increases are found more often in patents than scientific articles.

Figure 2.3 Share of patenting and scientific publishing in innovation-dense areas, by selected countries

Note: largest innovation-dense areas follow WIPO (2019), www.wipo.int/wipr.

Yet, while innovation tends to concentrate in large metropolitan areas, not all urban agglomerations concentrate on the equivalent level of innovation-related activities. Figure 2.4 displays the top thirty-five most-populated metropolitan areas in the world and their S&T outputs. Only twenty-two cities out of these are innovation-dense areas. The top-right quadrant shows that Beijing, London, Los Angeles, New York, Osaka, Paris, Seoul, and Tokyo concentrate a large amount of both patents and scientific publishing. In comparison, Shanghai is only less populated than Tokyo but has fewer patents and scientific publications than all of them. A second-tier group of innovation-dense areas include the metropolitan areas of cities such as Buenos Aires, Delhi, Istanbul, Mexico City, Moscow, São Paulo, and Tehran. Despite their large populations, they concentrate much fewer scientific publications and patents. Other densely populated cities such as Cairo, Bangkok, Kolkata, and Chongqing have only enough innovation density in some specialized scientific or technological fields. Last, in the bottom-left quadrant, Dhaka, Jakarta, Karachi, Lagos, Lima, and Manila do not have an innovation density corresponding to their highly populated metropolitan areas, despite concentrating most of their respective national S&T output. As noted, innovation is even more concentrated than general economic activity and population.

Figure 2.4 Population density does not ensure high innovation density

Patents and scientific articles in the top thirty-five largest cities, 1980–2016.

Source: WIPO (2019) based on PATSTAT, PCT, and Web of Science data, and top cities from The City Mayors Foundation (September 2019). Notes: Size of bubble refers to the metropolitan area population (circa 2017). Axis in logarithmic scale. Due to low scientific publication or patent values, Kinshasa and Shijiazhuang are omitted from the chart area.

Nevertheless, the lack of innovation-dense output in otherwise economically dense agglomerations is not exclusive to less developed economies. Even within high-income countries, the agglomeration of innovation activities seems to follow only partially the pattern of population and economic activity agglomeration.

2.1.3 A Concentrated Network of a Few Innovation-Dense Areas

Why does more collaboration not necessarily lead to less inequality in innovation distribution within and across countries?

The rising concentration of science and innovation production in innovation-dense areas, and the parallel global spreading out of innovation and international team formation, characterizes a globalized hub-to-hub system, which links national and regional systems of innovation and global firms through a spiky geography of knowledge creation (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019). Many of these hubs are better connected to one another than to their neighboring areas inside their countries. The collaborative scientific communities, the talented migrants, the supply chains, and the knowledge-seeking MNCs give rise to global innovation-dense “hotspots” around the world. The successful regions discussed earlier cannot rely uniquely on the local innovation ecosystem they form – whether private companies, higher-education or research institutions, etc. – but they build national and international links to complementary pools of knowledge abroad (Awate and Mudambi, Reference Awate and Mudambi2017; Bathelt et al., Reference Bathelt, Malmberg and Maskell2004; Lorenzen and Mudambi, Reference Lorenzen and Mudambi2013; Turkina and Van Assche, Reference Turkina and Van Assche2018).

Figure 17 by Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019) depicts the global network of highly connected innovation-dense areas. As expected, this network is denser within and between a few agglomerations in the United States, the United Kingdom, Germany, France, Japan, the Republic of Korea, China, and India. The United States, Germany, Japan, and the Republic of Korea also show thick national networks.

Even in these countries hosting most of the world’s innovation output, we observe that just a few innovation-dense areas concentrate most of the international connections. A handful of cities, mostly on the two coasts of the United States, account for much of the U.S. international coinventorship. Similarly, Western European innovation agglomerations connect mostly nationally to Paris, London, Frankfurt, and Berlin. Figuratively, these European innovation hubs mediate most of the other European international connections, as if they are Europe’s international “gatekeepers.” The same pattern happens in Asia, where Tokyo, Seoul, Beijing, Shanghai, Mumbai, and Bengaluru are the key gateways for international coinventions. The same analysis for scientific outputs would cast a much denser network but with an equivalent underlying pattern of concentration of international ties in a few hubs. In sum, S&T outputs are more likely to connect international partners if produced within these already concentrated innovation hotspots. The bias is even more apparent when focusing on the most valuable S&T output (Miguelez et al., Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019).

As a result, these global networks favor a few innovation-dense areas that concentrate the knowledge flows. This is a double-edged sword: While these areas spread knowledge, they do so mostly among themselves. The resulting GINs, in turn, cement the innovation “hotspot” advantages.

2.2 Consequences of the Unequal Innovation Distribution and Possible Policy Actions

We have just shown that the global production of innovation is extremely concentrated in a few areas of the world. Moreover, it is even more concentrated than other economic activities. Does this concentration pose a problem? What does it mean for economic and innovation policymaking? We attempt to answer these questions in three parts. First, we rely on the economic geography literature to explore in which ways this unequal distribution of innovative activity relates to one of the biggest challenges of present times, namely growing income inequality (Piketty and Saez, Reference Piketty and Saez2003). In particular, we will focus our attention on the relationship between innovation concentration and territorial income inequality. Second, we discuss if this unequal distribution of innovation (and income) across and within countries is inevitable. Last, we conclude by revisiting the role of policy in the light of our discussion.

2.2.1 Does the Unequal Distribution of Innovative Activity Really Matter?

Despite the global spread of knowledge production and the emergence of new local innovation giants (in both developed and developing countries), there remain high levels of within (and between) country concentration of innovation. Before diving into the role of policy, it is pertinent to ask if this is a problem that policy has to address.

In a simplified economic view, innovation and the knowledge to produce it have the characteristics of a public good (Arrow, Reference Arrow1962). Many individuals, firms, and regions can use at the same time the knowledge produced by others somewhere else, without rivaling the use by the originators. Indeed, artificial intelligence emerged from a limited number of scientific organizations in a few regions of the world, and today a large number of companies and individuals employ the underlying science for a wide variety of innovative applications around the world. A similar point can be made for mobile communications technology, which has flown to remote corners of the world.

In this sense, if innovation were a pure global public good, it would not necessarily matter where innovative activity takes place. In such a scenario, innovation would flow without attrition benefiting all regions equally. Moreover, there would be strong arguments in favor of agglomerating resources in a few regions to benefit from economies of scale, which will eventually flow to all regions in the world. The “new economic geography” (NEG) school of thought made a strong case that geographical concentration of economic activities is inevitable and even desirable. Regional concentration happens in an iterative manner, where regions progressively attract productive companies and skilled labor, which in turn makes them more attractive for new companies and workers to join the same region. The key to this school of thought is that circumstantial regional advantages in productivity can trigger divergent geographical concentration paths. This simple mechanism can explain how agglomerations emerge but also how existing ones can strengthen their position to the detriment of the outer regions (Krugman, Reference Krugman1991). In this scenario, mainstream theories predict that processes of inter-regional labor mobility, knowledge diffusion, and trickle-down effects will occur, and income convergence will follow. Thus, policy intervention to favor disadvantaged areas is not necessary (World Bank, 2009). This theoretical framework, implicitly, concerns innovation activities. too. While NEG early proponents dismissed high-tech sectors as a particular case, empirical evidence largely found that concentration is particularly salient in knowledge- and innovation-based economic activities (Audretsch and Feldman, Reference Audretsch and Feldman1996), which was largely attributed to the importance of LKS as a localization force (Jaffe et al., Reference Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson1993; Krugman, Reference Krugman2010).

But several recent economic studies suggest that converging mechanisms might not be working as predicted (Hope and Limberg, Reference Hope and Limberg2022; Iammarino et al., Reference Iammarino, Rodríguez-Pose and Storper2019). If the benefits of successful innovations depend on the location of innovation, patterns of agglomeration have a direct effect on spatial economic development outcomes, and while the concentration of innovation in a few places may benefit the worldwide rate of innovation, it also hinders the innovative prospects of other areas.

If innovation is indeed “sticky,” it is not a pure public good.Footnote 11 Why might this be the case? Beyond market size and talent availability, there are notable positive agglomeration externalities arising from knowledge spillovers (Jaffe et al., Reference Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson1993; Krugman, Reference Krugman2010). The tacit nature of knowledge makes the colocation of innovative firms, academic centers, and talented human resources a more effective environment for these externalities to arise (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019; WIPO, 2019: ch. 1). Information may flow relatively free over the geographical space, but knowledge flows are far less fluid. Trade flows, for instance, may help diffuse routinized and codified information, but knowledge that is not economically ubiquitous generates innovative rents to specific geographical locations (Feldman et al., Reference Feldman, Guy and Iammarino2021). When the codification of knowledge is difficult – that is, knowledge is more tacit – organizations and, especially, individuals have to physically move with the knowledge embedded in themselves to realize these knowledge flows. Movement of and interactions between individuals and organizations are invariably easier in close proximity. Global networks, such as GINs, while allegedly a mechanism of knowledge diffusion, end up reinforcing concentration effects, as different types of workers are differently exposed to offshoring and outsourcing (Autor and Handel, Reference Autor and Handel2013; Gagliardi et al., Reference Gagliardi, Iammarino and Rodríguez-Pose2021). A similar pattern holds for highly skilled migrants holding science and technology jobs, who tend to concentrate in innovative cities (Coda-Zabetta et al., Reference Coda-Zabetta, Chacua, Lissoni, Miguelez, Raffo, Yin, Castellani, Perri, Scalera and Zanfei2022).

As a consequence of the above, some scholars argue that the uneven distribution of science and technology, as well as skilled labor, has translated into rising levels of income inequality (Iammarino et al., Reference Iammarino, Rodríguez-Pose and Storper2019). This phenomenon occurs both inside highly innovative superstar cities, and between them and the rest of the country – the “Left Behind Regions” (Rodríguez-Pose, Reference Rodríguez-Pose2018). Starting in many developed countries from around 1980, this process of economic divergence is known as “the great inversion” (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019; Florida, Reference Florida2017; Kemeny and Storper, Reference Kemeny and Storper2020). Moreover, superstar cities and innovation-dense areas tend to host highly skilled, nonroutinized employment but also attract low-skilled, nonroutinized jobs. In such a scenario, inter-regional migration does not occur, either because of high housing costs in superstar cities, unaffordable for medium- and low-skilled workers, or simply because “skill requirements in these superstar cities tend to be both high and specific” (Kemeny and Storper, Reference Kemeny and Storper2020: 27). Meanwhile, this technological change also reduces employment in many previously dominant manufacturing sectors through automation (Iammarino et al., Reference Iammarino, Rodríguez-Pose and Storper2019).

Another related trend is growing evidence of falling R&D productivity. Recent empirical studies indicate that current technological progress is requiring increasingly more innovation investments (Bloom et al., Reference Bloom, Jones, Van Reenen and Webb2020). This is apparent in the information and communication technology (ICT) industries, for example, where continuously achieving Moore’s law – that is, doubling the number of transistors on a computer chip every two years – requires eighteen times more researchers than it did in the early 1970s. Other industries evidence a similar pattern: Increases in life expectancy or crop yields require much more investments in medical or agricultural R&D. The innovation frontier problems to be solved seem to be increasingly complex and, thus, requiring increasingly larger research teams and specialization (Hidalgo, Reference Hidalgo2021; WIPO, 2019: ch. 2). These R&D productivity trends have subsequent negative effects on overall productivity. Some economic scholars have indeed argued that current innovations boost economic productivity to a much smaller extent than the innovations associated with the Second Industrial Revolution (Gordon, Reference Gordon2018).

How does falling R&D productivity relate to geographical inequality? Falling R&D productivity makes a strong case for pooling resources to optimize the local knowledge spillovers. It might be socially desirable to concentrate innovation resources in a few hotspots in the world, but this may generate, again, a whole set of regional imbalances to be sorted out by policymakers. Regardless of which region or country emerges as the concentration champion, any resulting concentration implies a transition period during which large transfers of resources – including human capital – from noninnovation-dense areas occur. These transitions are usually – if not always – socially costly. There are also within-region imbalances. A side effect of innovation agglomeration is the centrifugal forces pushing less innovative firms and unskilled labor to the periphery of the innovation-dense areas. This is unquestionably one of the causes behind the rising housing prices and widening income disparities in Silicon Valley and more recently in Tel Aviv (Srivastava, Reference Srivastava2018).

2.2.2 Can Diverging Innovation Paths in Economies and Regions Be Changed? Lessons from Asia

We discussed in the previous sections how the geographical concentration of innovation can be instrumental for both regional and economy-wide development outcomes. We also pointed to the social costs associated with such concentration, mainly in terms of not all countries benefiting from the spread of the knowledge economy, and inter-regional income inequality rising even in highly innovative economies. We now turn to evidence on past geographical trends and discuss if and how policy may have played a role.

The global spread of knowledge production documented earlier, the existence of GINs, and the international flows of knowledge were probably necessary but not sufficient conditions for countries to successfully ignite economic development through technological change. Indeed, national innovation strategies and policies played a critical role in making this happen (Crescenzi et al., Reference Crescenzi, Iammarino, Ioramashvili, Rodríguez-Pose and Storpe2019). The most successful examples of technological catch-up are found in Asia. The spread of knowledge production and global networks toward these countries has coincided with the emergence of strong NIS in them. In turn, public R&D spending and public incentives to private spending, among other things, may have played a role in the development of these NIS (Archibugi and Filippetti, Reference Archibugi and Filippetti2018).

In what follows, we first focus on GDP and innovation concentration across countries, where more evidence and policy discussion have consistently emerged. In terms of overall development, there is still considerable variation in GDP per capita levels and growth across countries and within regions of the world. Asia as a region has the highest income per capita outside the Western world. Latin America, Africa, and, to some extent, the Middle East observe a less remarkable evolution (Figure 2.5).

Figure 2.5 Diverging growth paths

Real GDP per capita in 2011US$ (logs), selected economies

Sources: Maddison Project Database, version 2018. Bolt et al. (Reference Bolt, Inklaar, de Jong and van Zanden2018)

More recently, the evolution in GDP per capita has correlated with the increase in S&T outputs. Since the 2000s, Asia has increased its share of total patenting from 32 percent to 48 percent and its share of total scientific publishing from 17 percent to 36 percent. This reflects the rise of China and the Republic of Korea and comes despite the relative decline of Japan’s share of patents and publications. Furthermore, considering their low starting point, most selected Asian economies have seen a remarkable increase in their share of S&T outputs in a few decades (Table 2.1). Within these economies, Turkey, Israel, India, Singapore, and Iran stand out as the largest innovating economies.

Table 2.1 Evolution of patenting and scientific publishing, by selected countries

PatentsPublications
Country1970–19791980–19891990–19992000–20042005–20092010–20142015–20172000–20042005–20092010–20142015–2017
China0.007%0.064%0.275%1.313%4.043%8.164%13.671%2.446%4.370%7.848%12.011%
Rep. of Korea0.014%0.308%2.579%5.212%7.562%8.506%8.368%1.389%2.003%2.679%3.157%
Malaysia0.005%0.007%0.027%0.078%0.148%0.169%0.115%0.076%0.092%0.181%0.435%
India0.031%0.034%0.114%0.533%0.997%1.358%1.334%1.942%2.033%2.635%3.164%
Singapore0.005%0.015%0.118%0.308%0.358%0.372%0.343%0.302%0.428%0.474%0.495%
Israel0.239%0.312%0.576%0.931%1.148%1.083%1.047%0.930%0.908%0.763%0.615%
Iran0.006%0.003%0.005%0.007%0.017%0.023%0.053%0.116%0.258%0.817%1.555%
Turkey0.003%0.005%0.017%0.064%0.168%0.262%0.363%0.587%0.979%1.544%1.671%
Syria0.001%0.001%0.002%0.002%0.002%0.002%0.001%0.009%0.010%0.011%0.014%
Saudi Arabia0.003%0.007%0.009%0.014%0.031%0.103%0.166%0.165%0.137%0.122%0.305%
Brazil0.067%0.093%0.122%0.169%0.245%0.281%0.271%1.110%1.454%1.963%2.325%
Mexico0.077%0.048%0.063%0.091%0.107%0.123%0.149%0.442%0.514%0.576%0.593%
Argentina0.050%0.042%0.057%0.059%0.056%0.041%0.038%0.461%0.475%0.433%0.456%
Chile0.006%0.006%0.011%0.018%0.033%0.056%0.053%0.170%0.196%0.221%0.254%
Colombia0.007%0.006%0.008%0.015%0.021%0.032%0.038%0.042%0.053%0.091%0.141%
South Africa0.224%0.196%0.195%0.211%0.167%0.131%0.098%0.375%0.329%0.351%0.404%
Egypt0.002%0.003%0.005%0.013%0.026%0.026%0.021%0.245%0.266%0.294%0.395%
Nigeria0.001%0.001%0.001%0.002%0.002%0.003%0.002%0.081%0.072%0.131%0.128%
Kenya0.002%0.001%0.002%0.004%0.003%0.005%0.004%0.040%0.033%0.038%0.043%
Algeria0.000%0.001%0.001%0.003%0.003%0.003%0.003%0.029%0.043%0.078%0.105%

However, this does not mean that all cities from successful East Asian economies have followed the same pattern. Table 2.2 looks at the top three innovation-dense areas for selected countries in two different periods and the share of patenting and scientific publication they account for in their respective countries. First, the list of top innovation-dense areas per country barely differs in time and between patents and scientific publications, showing the stability of the concentration phenomenon. Second, in all countries shown, the share of the top three is quite high, ranging from around 20 percent up to more than 100 percent.Footnote 12 With the exception of Chinese and Indian patenting, the share of the top three patenting and publishing hotspots decreases over time, showing that, within countries, S&T activities seem to be spreading geographically. However, overall, the concentration of S&T output remains relatively high. China and India also show some dispersion trends in scientific publications, but their top three hotspots still hold about a quarter and a third of all national scientific publications, respectively.

Table 2.2 Top innovation-dense Asian agglomerations and national concentration of S&T outputs, 1991–1995 and 2011–2015, selected economies

CountryPatentsPublications
1991–1995%2011–2015%2001–2005%2011–2015%
China

Shenzhen-Hong Kong

Beijing

Shanghai

48.5

Shenzhen-Hong Kong

Beijing

Shanghai

51.0

Beijing

Shanghai

Nanjing

43.9

Beijing

Shanghai

Nanjing

35.8
India

Bengaluru

Mumbai

Delhi

41.5

Bengaluru

Hyderabad

Delhi

46.2

Delhi

Mumbai

Bengaluru

27.7

Delhi

Mumbai

Kolkata

24.6
IranNDNDNDNDTehran57.6Tehran46.1
Israel

Tel Aviv

Haifa

Jerusalem

85.6

Tel Aviv

Haifa

Jerusalem

82.3

Tel Aviv

Jerusalem

Haifa

86.4

Tel Aviv

Haifa

Jerusalem

86.1
Rep. of Korea

Seoul

Daejeon

Icheon-si

75.8

Seoul

Daejeon

Beolgyo

70.3

Seoul

Daejeon

Busan

71.3

Seoul

Daejeon

Busan

69.9
MalaysiaKuala Lumpur61.5Kuala Lumpur58.0Kuala Lumpur51.4Kuala Lumpur59.4
Saudi ArabiaDammam42.4Dammam38.8Dammam21.0Dammam7.8
SingaporeSingapore100.8Singapore100.3Singapore100.0Singapore100.0
Turkey

Istanbul

Ankara

59.1

Istanbul

Ankara

38.8

Ankara

Istanbul

46.5

Ankara

Istanbul

42.8

Notes: Up to three top innovation-dense agglomerations displayed per country, in case of more than one found by the algorithm. Some agglomerations may exceed the national borders (e.g., Singapore). “ND” = No data available.

Did national and regional policies play a role in such divergent economic performance? At the national level, economic scholars are still quite divided. There is not even full consensus on the source of the divergent paths. Development economists enumerate, among the possible sources of diverging economic performance, insufficient capital accumulation (Young, Reference Young1995, Reference Young2000a, Reference Young2000b), a distorted size of the natural resource sector (Sachs and Warner, Reference Sachs and Warner1995), and declining terms of trade for low value-added goods (Prebisch, Reference Prebisch1962). Alternative theories give more prominence to the role of institutions in economic growth (North, Reference North1990) and their capacity to absorb new technologies (Nelson and Pack, Reference Nelson and Pack1999).

Historically, several policies to solve a suspected natural resource disadvantage and declining terms of trade have been suggested, mostly based on import substitution and state-led industrialization (e.g., Prebisch, Reference Prebisch1962; Singer, Reference Singer1950). They coincided with high sustained returns to capital investment in Asia, with the capacity of absorbing new technologies playing a crucial role (Nelson and Park, Reference Nelson and Pack1999), which in turn set the grounds for rapid capital accumulation. As a synthesis, institutional characteristics related to innovation such as education, R&D, S&T infrastructure, and science–industry linkages can go a long way in explaining why some Asian economies outperformed the rest of the developing world (Freeman, Reference Freeman1995).

2.2.3 What Is the Role for Policy?

In the context of an uneven geographical distribution of innovation, the relevant question for policymakers is what type of policies can stimulate the institutional environment that better attracts external innovation – that is, technological absorption – and, in turn, better generates new technologies. Traditionally, this question was often simplified as to either favor market liberalizing policies or government interventionist ones.Footnote 13

When it comes to dealing with the unequal distribution of innovation and income, in both developed and developing countries, a similar trade-off arises between efficiency and equity (Iammarino et al., Reference Iammarino, Rodríguez-Pose and Storper2019). Efficiency reasons may suggest allowing market forces to generate as many agglomerations as possible, which might be the most efficient for the whole economy, with spatial equity occurring through a trickle-down process – for example, through labor mobility (Glaeser, Reference Glaeser2011; World Bank, 2009). Equity concerns may call for greater intervention to directly achieve some redistribution, even at the expense of damaging national champions and overall economic growth. The chosen approach to solving problems of between- and within-country income inequality may determine the chosen type of policies, too: spatially blind policies versus spatially based ones. Again, the former advocates for policies that apply to all locations, without accounting for space and the local context (e.g., regulations ensuring market efficiency), as spatially targeted approaches may deter growth coming from agglomerations (mostly represented by the World Bank’s (2009) report, focused on developing countries). The latter prefers policies highly contingent on context, rooted in the local community and local stakeholders (Barca et al., Reference Barca, McCann and Rodríguez‐Pose2012). One approach is based on the need for full-fledged market forces to let Schumpeter’s creative destruction of firms and sectors to take place. The other bases its logic on the existence of negative externalities hampering the development of such innovative capacity, which only government policy can overcome. Both underlying economic theories are sound, but the practical policy setups can easily differ.

Arguably, any past policy successes in boosting national technological capacity might not be as relevant in the current context. As innovation is increasingly fragmented in innovation-dense metropolitan areas, which astonishingly are more globally interconnected, a different policy toolbox may be necessary. Likewise, the increasing international interconnectivity of innovation hotspots is also the result of national and multilateral policies promoting openness and international cooperation. The institutional setup favoring openness and cooperation should not be taken for granted, as recently public perception has become more skeptical of the benefits of openness (WIPO, 2019: ch. 5).

Any reduced openness of innovation ecosystems will likely affect the rate of knowledge diffusion. Knowledge may not flow across borders as much if researchers cannot move around the world or access scientific journals and patent documents published elsewhere. Limitations to international trade can also impact innovation openness, as a substantial part of technological flows happens through imported parts and components.

However, there are also limits to how widely knowledge can be shared. In fact, we have discussed in Section 2.1 how concentrated the production of new S&T knowledge is within and across countries. Still there are mutual gains for openness, if outward knowledge flows increase economic benefits abroad without reducing the local use. But several opinions perceive innovation as a zero-sum game, where breakthrough innovation can provide a competitive advantage to regions or countries. In the long run, this perspective has little base, as both winning and losing economies will find new equilibria where they are better off. Nevertheless, there are extreme scenarios where such “zero-sum” outcomes could happen (Grossman and Helpman, Reference Grossman and Helpman1991).

In the short run, things might be different. As discussed earlier, regional differences in productivity and innovativeness can lead to divergent paths of geographical distribution within countries of incomes, technology production, high-skilled employment, and wages. Regional competitive advantages can have profound negative effects for some regions in the short run, as it takes time to reconvert human capital to new industrial needs. Indeed, in the United States, as mentioned earlier, regional divergence started to accelerate in the 1980s and 1990s, after decades of postwar convergence (Ganong and Shoag, Reference Ganong and Shoag2017). The same applies to the European context since the great recession in 2008 (Alcidi et al., Reference Alcidi, Núñez Ferrer, Di Salvo, Pilati and Musmeci2018). Moreover, such inequality is also likely to sprout within successful regions. Vibrant innovation hotspots may produce spiked salaries of highly skilled workers, putting upward pressure on local prices, especially for housing, and directly affecting the disposable income of low-skilled workers (see WIPO, 2019: chs. 1 and 5).

How to address such rising regional imbalances is probably one of the most challenging questions that regional policymakers face in current times. Counter-weighing the agglomeration forces of the main national innovation hubs might not be the best policy strategy, as it might affect the national innovation outcomes. More importantly, being realistic, it might not even be possible. Similarly, redirecting inward the international connections of the globally successful regions may not have the desired effect and risks slowing down the technological diffusion toward all hubs in the country.

The key problem might be clear, but its solutions are probably not. Labor, capital, and the companies containing these only gradually move from lingering regions to successful innovation agglomerations. Accelerating the structural transformation of economic activity might reduce imbalances, but the social impact might leave long-lasting scars. Individuals, in particular, are geographically bounded, as they may not have the capacity or willingness to move. Public and other supporting institutions – government agencies, schools, transport, etc. – are also extremely hard to transplant geographically.

Alternatively, policy can be directed to mitigate the agglomeration forces by simply financially supporting declining regions. The beneficial social contention of these policies is without question here, but the long-lasting economic results have less consensus. Yet, there are some relevant lessons worth having in mind when designing such policies (Foray, Reference Foray2015; Rodríguez-Pose, Reference Rodríguez-Pose2018). First, any regional development policy should aim at enhancing existing local advantages by investing in infrastructure, education, and technology. Second, the process of identifying existing capabilities has to rely on inputs from a broad array of local stakeholders. Regional advantages can take several forms – for example, relatively cheap land or labor, existing industrial capabilities, or reputational assets – but, by all means, they have to avoid formulaic solutions transposed from unalike regions.Footnote 14 Third, any implemented policies should be assessed regularly. By policy design, distortions will arise if the policies are successful, which inevitably imply that there will be winners and losers within the targeted region.

Is there a specific role for IP policies? History and the rather limited empirical evidence suggest that policies related to IP strengthening played a side part in the industrial development process of countries, and even more of regions.Footnote 15 What could be the channel where IP – especially patents – could affect innovation geographical concentration and spread? This is not as straightforward as many would think about it.

In most cases, IP rights have a national jurisdiction, which can be extended to other national jurisdictions. With a valid IP right within a country, right holders could use their IP to exclude the access of competitors to the technology or brand as much inside a cluster than in the neighboring areas outside the cluster. Internationally, holders can, and often do, use their IP to exclude competitors to produce in or export to protected jurisdictions. Still, there is no evidence of the reciprocal being clearly the case. Patent protection for technologies is low in many jurisdictions, yet these technologies do not diffuse to all countries and regions equally. In other words, the fact that large proportions of patented technologies do not have enforceable rights in other countries does not necessarily generate technological diffusion. This is mostly a result of the different local innovation capabilities to exploit the existing technologies, regardless of whether they are publicly available or not.

Overall, there is ample theoretical and empirical literature on how different standards of IP protection affect technology transfer, foreign direct investment (FDI), trade flows, and domestic innovation in developing economies, which Keun Lee’s chapter in this volume discusses in further detail (see Chapter 4). Two elements are however worth recalling: (i) most patent rights are not protected in poorer economies because of a lack of imitative threat, and (ii) those economies (notably China and the Republic of Korea) that successfully integrated in GINs did so through firms that pro-actively built up patent portfolios (mostly in relation to information technology), mainly to be able to export to rich country markets.

This is not to say that IP cannot be a useful policy instrument to overcome market failures related to knowledge as a public good. Indeed, all the core innovation hotspots show an intensive use of the IP system, both nationally and internationally.

It is also important to mention that IP policies always interact with other public policy tools – namely public funding of R&D activities and infrastructure – aiming at stimulating innovation activity in the private sector. Interestingly, outside the core innovation countries and regions of the world, we do observe a promising increase in scientific activity, but we fail to observe the equivalent use of the patent system. Indeed, in these peripheral regions, most of the patenting results from research produced in universities and research institutions, which are largely publicly funded. It is not always clear to what extent patented inventions are then transformed into commercialized products.

Innovation policies – and IP policies within these – that stimulate the participation of the private sector in the creation of new knowledge and technologies could go a long way toward improving the local innovation ecosystem of these economies. Embedding IP into the targeted regional capability-enhancing policies described earlier is certainly a complementary and feasible strategy. Policymakers should be actively conscious of any cumbersome IP procedures or other barriers preventing local entrepreneurs and companies from using the IP system efficiently. They should also be realistic about policy priorities, as in many cases innovation is hampered by other more pressing matters than IP.

2.3 Conclusions

In this chapter, we have revisited empirically the unequal geographical distribution of innovation by exploiting rich data from international patent applications and scientific articles.

Despite some new countries – notably in Asia – joining the traditional core economies in the production of new S&T outputs, the global spread of innovation remains limited. Our analysis also shows that, within these economies, the production of innovation is unevenly concentrated in large metropolitan areas.

The secular trends offer some room for optimism, especially if the technologies reducing the cost and enhancing the quality of interconnectivity keep progressing. Our analysis supports in part such optimism. Innovation-related collaboration, in general, and international collaboration, in particular, are mostly increasing. The challenges observed relate to who would reap more benefits from such enhanced connectivity. Indeed, our analysis also shows that, in the current form, the global network of S&T flows is largely concentrated as well. Only a few economies, and a few hotspots within these, represent the bulk of the connections.

There is also some room for pessimism. Recent years show some increase in innovation concentration. Indicators of R&D investments and international patents – especially those highly cited or relating to high-tech or complex technologies – evidence a reconcentration pattern since the second half of the 2000s. Hopefully, this process may just be the result of a new cycle of breakthrough innovation, led by more technologically advanced countries and regions (Kemeny and Storper, Reference Kemeny and Storper2020). If this is the case, we expect that technological diffusion – and the associated geographical innovation spread – will resume shortly. Nonetheless, it is also apparent in our analysis that only a few countries and regions will act as the main gateways to access the new technology.

Part of the unequal geographical distribution of innovation seems unsolvable by itself, as the economic benefits of agglomeration go far beyond innovation. Nevertheless, we have also documented that innovation is much more geographically skewed – both nationally and subnationally – than other economic activities. This increases the challenge faced by policymakers. National policymakers around the world are already struggling with the problems that regional disparities of income, unemployment, or infrastructure convey. More skewed innovation outputs and flows just make their tasks even harder.

Last, we give some thoughts about what policy consensus the innovation and economic geography literatures can offer. We make the case for national and regional innovation policies that are balanced and attainable. It is always a good practice to acknowledge that these policies are likely to have distributional consequences within countries and regions.

In the context of growing skepticism toward multilateralism after the Great Recession, we also discuss the benefits of openness, as it should not be taken for granted. Certain signs of globalization reversal – or slowbalization – are troubling. The increasing self-sufficiency of the largest innovation hotspots and their isolation in an exclusive innovation network could be really bad news for economies and regions aspiring to catch up technologically and, in turn, economically.

Footnotes

* Disclaimer: The views expressed in this chapter are the authors’ own and do not necessarily reflect the views of WIPO or its member states.

Acknowledgments: We are deeply grateful to Christian Chacua, Massiliano Coda-Zabetta, Francesco Lissoni, and Yin Deyun for our joint research on the topic of geography of innovation, which has contributed greatly to this chapter. We are also thankful for comments from the editors, as well as Kevin Lee and Francesco Lissoni. Ernest Miguelez acknowledges financial support from the French National Research Agency (TKC project – reference: ANR-17-CE26–0016).

1 This section relies substantially on the research performed in Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019) and WIPO (2019). Please refer to them for further details.

2 In the spirit of Marshall (Ellison et al., Reference Ellison, Glaeser and Kerr2010; Marshall, Reference Marshall and Abridged1920), arguably the barriers to perfect knowledge diffusion relate to the cost of moving goods, people, and ideas that carry the knowledge in a physical, codified, or tacit manner. These costs can arise from not only economic forces but also national and international legal frameworks. Hence, the legal frameworks regulating the trade of goods and services, the mobility of workers, or the transfer of IP rights could have an impact on the rate of knowledge diffusion.

3 The GINs framework covers several related approaches, such as Coe and Bunnell’s (Reference Coe and Bunnell2003) “transnational innovation networks.”

4 During this period, several of these economies benefited from less restrictive IP frameworks, making some scholars claim a causality. Yet, many other countries – from the same and other regions – also had equally less stringent national IP laws but did not observe the same innovation boom. We discussed elsewhere (Fink and Raffo, Reference Fink, Raffo, Correa and Seuba2019) that “[i]n the end, similar to other hypothesized determinants of industrial development and growth, we are doubtful that there is an unambiguous effect of ‘IP strength’ waiting to be discovered. This is not only because of the varying role of different IP policies in different sectors, but also because IP policies interact with other elements of the broader innovation ecosystem.” In Chapter 1 in this volume, Keith Maskus indicates a similar reservation about the potential causality between growth of inequality and IP rights.

5 For more details on the sources and methodology, see Miguelez et al. (Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019) and WIPO (2019: technical annex).

6 Indeed, more valuable patents and scientific outputs – as measured by citations – show Herfindahl-Hirschman Index values even higher than all the indicators reported in Figure 2.2 (see Miguelez et al., Reference Miguelez, Raffo, Chacua, Coda-Zabetta, Yin, Lissoni and Tarasconi2019).

7 Ellison et al. (Reference Ellison, Glaeser and Kerr2010) summarize Marshall’s (Reference Marshall and Abridged1920) economies as “the cost of moving goods, people, and ideas that can be reduced by industrial agglomeration. … Firms … in Silicon Valley, locate near one another to learn and to speed their rate of innovation.” According to Ellison and his coauthors’ review, in industrial and high-density human-capital concentrations, workers learn skills quicker from each other and businesses exchange more information and benefit more from specialized networks, ultimately speeding up the flows of ideas within the cluster.

8 Despite the sizeable evidence on the benefits of tech clustering for innovation activities, research has also found that, under certain circumstances, locating out of clusters may bring benefits to innovative firms. Oakey and Cooper (Reference Oakey and Cooper1989) find that the peripheral location of high-technology firms can be driven by the benefits from high natural amenities. Suarez-Villa and Walrod (Reference Suarez-Villa and Walrod1997) find that, in the case of Los Angeles advanced electronic sectors, “non-clustered locations may have … become attractive alternatives to clusters for many firms, and particularly so with respect to R&D, where privacy is usually regarded as a major concern. Not locating in a cluster may have also been an advantage in its own right, as some firms sought to maintain some independence and secrecy for their R&D activities.”

9 In Krugman’s (Reference Krugman1991: 483) words,

one of the most remarkable things about the United States is that in a generally sparsely populated country, much of whose land is fertile, the bulk of the population resides in a few clusters of metropolitan areas; a quarter of the inhabitants are crowded into a not especially inviting section of the East Coast. It has often been noted that nighttime satellite photos of Europe reveal little of political boundaries but clearly suggest a center-periphery pattern whose hub is somewhere in or near Belgium.

Indeed, many clusters fall in the definition of transnational innovation systems, particularly in Europe (Chaminade and Nielsen, Reference Chaminade and Nielsen2011).

10 For all the quantitative discussion in this section, we use WIPO’s (2019) definition of the 487 most innovation-dense areas of the world (GIHs and NCs), which are the densest agglomeration of innovation activities as measured by scientific publications and international patent families by km2. Most of the statistics discussed would show little variation with other definitions, and much less differences on the substance discussed.

11 Exclusive IP rights may also erode the notion of innovation as a pure public good. However, IP rights do not turn knowledge into an eternal private good. They are territorial in nature and time bound; most patents, in particular, are only registered in selected high-income economies, and they only last for a maximum of twenty years. Even while they are protected, patents can be licensed, thus enabling knowledge adoption by others. Finally, the patent system offers incentives for knowledge disclosure, which ultimately promotes dissemination. The full effectiveness of IP as means of diffusion is still argued in the innovation economic literature, yet several studies have found evidence of patents being an effective source of knowledge. See, among others, Cohen et al. (Reference Cohen, Goto, Nagata, Nelson and Walsh2002), Denicolò and Franzoni (Reference Denicolò and Franzoni2003), Graham et al. (Reference Graham, Merges, Samuelson and Sichelman2009), Jaffe et al. (Reference Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Fogarty2000), and Moser (Reference Moser2011).

12 Singapore innovation agglomeration exceeds the national boundaries.

13 World Bank (1993) and Amsden (Reference Amsden1994) are samples of these rivaling perspectives.

14 History provides a vast collection of failed “new” Silicon Valleys, while there are several examples of regions specializing “smartly” in a given technology exploiting their relative knowledge and natural advantages. See several examples for Latin American–specific clusters in Pietrobelli and Rabellotti (Reference Pietrobelli and Rabellotti2006).

References

Alcidi, C., Núñez Ferrer, J., Di Salvo, M., Pilati, M., and Musmeci, R.. 2018. “Income Convergence in the EU: A Tale of Two Speeds.” www.ceps.eu/ceps-publications/income-convergence-eu-tale-two-speeds/.Google Scholar
Amendolagine, V., Chaminade, C., Guimón, J., and Rabellotti, R.. 2019. “Cross-Border Knowledge Flows through R&D FDI: Implications for Low- and Middle-Income Countries.” In Trade in Knowledge: Intellectual Property, Trade and Development in a Transformed Global Economy, edited by Taubman, Antony and Watal, Jayashree, 352375. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Amsden, A.H. 1994. “Why Is Not the Whole World Experimenting with the East Asian Model to Develop? Review of the East Asian Miracle.” World Development 22(4): 627633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Archibugi, D., and Filippetti, A.. 2018. “The Retreat of Public Research and Its Adverse Consequences on Innovation.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 127: 97111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K.J. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing.” Review of Economic Studies 29: 155173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asheim, B.T., and Gertler, M.S.. 2005. “The Geography of Innovation: Regional Innovation Systems.” In The Oxford Handbook of Innovation, edited by Fagerberg, Jan and Mowery, David C., 291317. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Audretsch, D.B., and Feldman, M.P.. 1996. “R&D Spillovers and the Geography of Innovation and Production.” American Economic Review 86(3): 630640.Google Scholar
Autor, D.H., and Handel, M.J.. 2013. “Putting Tasks to the Test: Human Capital, Job Tasks, and Wages.” Journal of Labor Economics 31(2): S59S96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Awate, S., Larsen, M.M., and Mudambi, R.. 2012. “EMNE Catch‐Up Strategies in the Wind Turbine Industry: Is There a Trade‐Off between Output and Innovation Capabilities?” Global Strategy Journal 2(3): 205223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Awate, S., and Mudambi, R.. 2017. “On the Geography of Emerging Industry Technological Networks: The Breadth and Depth of Patented Innovations.” Journal of Economic Geography 18(2): 391419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barca, F., McCann, P., and Rodríguez‐Pose, A.. 2012. “The Case for Regional Development Intervention: Place‐Based versus Place‐Neutral Approaches.” Journal of Regional Science 52(1): 134152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bathelt, H., Malmberg, A., and Maskell, P.. 2004. “Clusters and Knowledge: Local Buzz, Global Pipelines and the Process of Knowledge Creation.” Progress in Human Geography 28(1): 3156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkes, E., and Gaetani, R.. 2021. “The Geography of Unconventional Innovation.” Economic Journal 131: 14661514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, N., Jones, C.I., Van Reenen, J., and Webb, M.. 2020. “Are Ideas Getting Harder to Find?” American Economic Review 110(4): 11041144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolt, J., Inklaar, R., de Jong, H., and van Zanden, J.L.. 2018. “Rebasing ‘Maddison’: New Income Comparisons and the Shape of Long-Run Economic Development.” Groningen Growth and Development Centre Research Memorandum No. 174. University of Groningen. www.rug.nl/ggdc/html_publications/memorandum/gd174.pdf.Google Scholar
Branstetter, L., Li, G., and Veloso, F.. 2014. “The Rise of International Coinvention.” In The Changing Frontier: Rethinking Science and Innovation Policy, edited by Jaffe, Adam B. and Jones, Benjamin F., 135168. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Breschi, S., Lawson, C., Lissoni, F., Morrison, A., and Salter, A.. 2020. “STEM Migration, Research, and Innovation.” Research Policy 49(9): 104070.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breschi, S., Lissoni, F., and Miguelez, E.. 2017. “Foreign-Origin Inventors in the USA: Testing for Diaspora and Brain Gain Effects.” Journal of Economic Geography 17(5): 10091038.Google Scholar
Carlino, G., and Kerr, W.R.. 2015. “Agglomeration and Innovation.” In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, edited by Duranton, Gilles, Henderson, J. Vernon, and Strange, William, 349404. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Castellacci, F., and Archibugi, D.. 2008. “The Technology Clubs: The Distribution of Knowledge across Nations.” Research Policy 37(10): 16591673.Google Scholar
Castellani, D. 2018. “The Changing Geography of Innovation and the Multinational Enterprise.” In The Routledge Companion to the Geography of International Business, edited by Cook, Gary, Johns, Jennifer, McDonald, Frank, Beaverstock, Jonathan, and Pandit, Naresh, 454474. Abingdon: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castellani, D., and Zanfei, A.. 2006. Multinational Firms, Innovation and Productivity. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castellani, D., and Zanfei, A.. 2007. “Multinational Companies and Productivity Spillovers: Is There a Specification Error?” Applied Economics Letters 14(14): 10471051.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaminade, C., De Fuentes, C., Harirchi, G., and Plechero, M.. 2016. “The Geography and Structure of Global Innovation Networks: Global Scope and Regional Embeddedness.” In Handbook on the Geographies of Innovation, edited by Shearmur, Richard G., Doloreux, David, and Carrincazeaux, Christophe, 370381. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Chaminade, C., and Nielsen, H.. 2011. “Transnational Innovation Systems.” Serie Estudios y Perspectivas No. 133. ECLAC, Mexico.Google Scholar
Coda-Zabetta, M., Chacua, C., Lissoni, F., Miguelez, E., Raffo, J., and Yin, D.. 2022. “The Missing Link: International Migration in Global Clusters of Innovation.” In Cross-Border Innovation in a Changing World: Players, Places, and Policies, edited by Castellani, Davide, Perri, Alessandra, Scalera, Vittoria G., and Zanfei, Antonello, 82109. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coe, N.M., and Bunnell, T.G.. 2003. “‘Spatializing’ Knowledge Communities: Towards a Conceptualization of Transnational Innovation Networks.” Global Networks 3(4): 437456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, W.M., Goto, A., Nagata, A., Nelson, R.R., and Walsh, J.P.. 2002. “R&D Spillovers, Patents and the Incentives to Innovate in Japan and the United States.” Research Policy 31: 13491367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Comin, D., and Mestieri, M.. 2018. “If Technology Has Arrived Everywhere, Why Has Income Diverged?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10(3): 137178.Google Scholar
Crescenzi, R., Iammarino, S., Ioramashvili, C., Rodríguez-Pose, A., and Storpe, M.. 2019. “The Geography of Innovation: Local Hotspots and Global Innovation Networks.” WIPO Economic Research Working Paper No. 57.Google Scholar
Denicolò, V., and Franzoni, L.A.. 2003. “The Contract Theory of Patents.” International Review of Law and Economics 23: 365380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunning, J.H. 1998. “Location and the Multinational Enterprise: A Neglected Factor.” Journal of International Business Studies 29(1): 4566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edquist, C. 1997. “Systems of Innovation: Approaches – Their Emergence and Characteristics.” In Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations, edited by Edquist, Charles, 135. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ellison, G., Glaeser, E.L., and Kerr, W.R.. 2010. “What Causes Industry Agglomeration? Evidence from Coagglomeration Patterns.” American Economic Review 100(3): 11951213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, J.S. 2015. “Global Clusters of Innovation: Lessons from Silicon Valley.” https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/abs/10.1525/cmr.2015.57.2.36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, J.S., and del-Palacio, I.. 2009. “Global Networks of Clusters of Innovation: Accelerating the Innovation Process.” Business Horizons 52(5): 493503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, M., Guy, F., and Iammarino, S.. 2021. “Regional Income Disparities, Monopoly and Finance.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 14(1): 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fink, C., and Raffo, J.. 2019. “What Role for Intellectual Property in Industrial Development?” In Intellectual Property and Development: Understanding the Interfaces, edited by Correa, Carlos and Seuba, Xavier, 119136. Singapore: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Florida, R. 2017. The New Urban Crisis: How Our Cities Are Increasing Inequality, Deepening Segregation, and Failing the Middle Class – And What We Can Do about It. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Foley, C.F., and Kerr, W.R.. 2013. “Ethnic Innovation and U.S. Multinational Firm Activity.” Management Science 59(7): 15291544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foray, D. 2015. Smart Specialisation: Opportunities and Challenges for Regional Innovation Policy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Franzoni, C., Scellato, G., and Stephan, P.. 2012. “Foreign Born Scientists: Mobility Patterns for Sixteen Countries.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 18067.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, C. 1995. “The ‘National System of Innovation’ in Historical Perspective.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 19(1): 524.Google Scholar
Gagliardi, L., Iammarino, S., and Rodríguez-Pose, A.. 2021. “Exposure to OFDI and Regional Labour Markets: Evidence for Routine and Non-routine Jobs in Great Britain.” Journal of Economic Geography 21(5): 783806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganong, P., and Shoag, D.. 2017. “Why Has Regional Income Convergence in the US Declined?” Journal of Urban Economics 102: 7690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerybadze, A., and Merk, S.. 2014. “Globalisation of R&D and Host-Country Patenting of Multinational Corporations in Emerging Countries.” International Journal of Technology Management 64: 148179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, E. 2011. Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes US Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier and Happier. New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E.L., Kallal, H.D., Scheinkman, J.A., and Shleifer, A.. 1992. “Growth in Cities.” Journal of Political Economy 100(6): 11261152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, R.J. 2018. “Why Has Economic Growth Slowed When Innovation Appears to Be Accelerating?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 24554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, S.J., Merges, R.P., Samuelson, P., and Sichelman, T.. 2009. “High Technology Entrepreneurs and the Patent System: Results of the 2008 Berkeley Patent Survey.” Berkeley Technology Law Journal 24(4): 12551327.Google Scholar
Grossman, G., and Helpman, E.. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hidalgo, C.A. 2021. “Economic Complexity Theory and Applications.” Nature Reviews Physics 3: 92113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hope, D., and Limberg, J.. 2022. “The Economic Consequences of Major Tax Cuts for the Rich.” Socio-Economic Review 20(2): 539559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iammarino, S., Rodríguez-Pose, A., and Storper, M.. 2019. “Regional Inequality in Europe: Evidence, Theory and Policy Implications.” Journal of Economic Geography 19(2): 273298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, J. 1969. The Economy of Cities. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., and Fogarty, M.S.. 2000. “Knowledge Spillovers and Patent Citations: Evidence from a Survey of Inventors.” American Economic Review 90(2): 215218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M., and Henderson, R.. 1993. “Geographic Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 577598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemeny, T. 2011. “Are International Technology Gaps Growing or Shrinking in the Age of Globalization?” Journal of Economic Geography 11(1): 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemeny, T., and Storper, M.. 2020. “Superstar Cities and Left-Behind Places: Disruptive Innovation, Labor Demand, and Interregional Inequality.” LSE International Inequalities Institute Working Paper No. 41. London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Kerr, W.R., and Robert-Nicoud, F.. 2020. “Tech Clusters.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 34(3): 5076.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, V.V., Patra, S.K., and Bhattacharya, S.. 2012. “Internationalisation of R&D and Global Nature of Innovation: Emerging Trends in India.” Science, Technology and Society 17(2): 165199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, P. 1991. Geography and Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Krugman, P. 2010. “The New Economic Geography, Now Middle-Aged.” Regional Studies 45(1): 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorenzen, M., and Mudambi, R.. 2013. “Clusters, Connectivity and Catch-up: Bollywood and Bangalore in the Global Economy.” Journal of Economic Geography 13(3): 501534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of Economics, Abridged, ed. New York: Cosimo Classics.Google Scholar
Miguelez, E., Raffo, J., Chacua, C., Coda-Zabetta, M., Yin, D., Lissoni, F., and Tarasconi, G.. 2019. “Tied In: The Global Network of Local Innovation.” WIPO Economic Research Working Paper No. 58.Google Scholar
Moreno, R., and Miguélez, E.. 2012. “A Relational Approach to the Geography of Innovation: A Typology of Regions.” Journal of Economic Surveys 26(3): 492516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, P. 2011. “Do Patents Weaken the Localization of Innovations? Evidence from World’s Fairs.” Journal of Economic History 71: 363382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R.R., and Pack, H.. 1999. The Asian Miracle and Modern Growth Theory. Economic Journal 109: 416436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nijkamp, P., and Kourtit, K.. 2013. “The ‘New Urban Europe’: Global Challenges and Local Responses in the Urban Century.” European Planning Studies 21: 291315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oakey, R.P., and Cooper, S.Y.. 1989. “High Technology Industry, Agglomeration and the Potential for Peripherally Sited Small Firms.” Regional Studies 23(4): 347360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patel, P., and Pavitt, K.. 1991. “Large Firms in the Production of the World’s Technology: An Important Case of ‘Non-Globalisation.’Journal of International Business Studies 22(1): 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pietrobelli, C., and Rabellotti, R., eds. 2006. Upgrading to Compete: Global Value Chains, Clusters, and SMEs in Latin America. Cambridge: Inter-American Development Bank.Google Scholar
Piketty, T., and Saez, E.. 2003. “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1): 141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, M.E. 2000. “Location, Competition, and Economic Development: Local Clusters in a Global Economy.” Economic Development Quarterly 14(1): 1534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prebisch, R. 1962. “The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems.” Economic Bulletin for Latin America 7(1): 122.Google Scholar
Reddy, P. 1997. “New Trends in Globalization of Corporate R&D and Implications for Innovation Capability in Host Countries: A Survey from India.” World Development 25(11): 18211837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodríguez-Pose, A. 2018. “The Revenge of the Places That Do Not Matter (and What to Do about It).” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 11(1): 189209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J.D., and Warner, A.M.. 1995. “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saxenian, A. 2002. “Silicon Valley’s New Immigrant High-Growth Entrepreneurs.” Economic Development Quarterly 16(1): 2031.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saxenian, A. 2006. The New Argonauts: Regional Advantage in a Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Singer, H.W. 1950. “The Distribution of Gains between Investing and Borrowing Countries.” American Economic Review 40(2): 473485.Google Scholar
Srivastava, M. 2018. “Israel’s Tech Expansion Stokes Glaring Inequality in Tel Aviv.” Financial Times, December 10. www.ft.com/content/9836aa92-f235-11e8-ae55-df4bf40f9d0d.Google Scholar
Suarez-Villa, L., and Walrod, W.. 1997. “Operational Strategy, R&D and Intra-Metropolitan Clustering in a Polycentric Structure: The Advanced Electronics Industries of the Los Angeles Basin.” Urban Studies 34(9): 13431380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turkina, E., and Van Assche, A.. 2018. “Global Connectedness and Local Innovation in Industrial Clusters.” Journal of International Business Studies 49: 706728.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Useche, D., Miguelez, E., and Lissoni, F.. 2020. “Highly Skilled and Well Connected: Migrant Inventors in Cross-Border M&As.” Journal of International Business Studies 51: 737763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank. 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2009. World Development Report: Reshaping Economic Geography. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO). 2015. World Intellectual Property Report 2015: Breakthrough Innovation and Economic Growth. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization.Google Scholar
World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO). 2019. World Intellectual Property Report 2019: The Geography of Innovation: Local Hotspots, Global Networks. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization.Google Scholar
Young, A. 1995. “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 641680.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. 2000a. “Gold into Base Metals: Productivity Growth in the People’s Republic of China during the Reform Period.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7856.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. 2000b. “The Razor’s Edge: Distortions and Incremental Reform in the People’s Republic of China.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(4): 10911135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, Y., and Xin, T.. 2003. “An Innovative Region in China: Interaction between Multinational Corporations and Local Firms in a High-Tech Cluster in Beijing.” Economic Geography 79(2): 129152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 2.1

Figure 1

Figure 2.1

Source: Miguelez et al. (2019). Notes: RoW = Rest of the World. See WIPO (2019), technical notes (www.wipo.int/wipr)
Figure 2

Figure 2.2 Innovation is more concentrated than other economic activitiesHerfindahl–Hirschman index, selected innovation and economic indicators, 1980–2016.

Source: Authors based on PATSTAT, PCT, and Web of Science data. R&D and R&D personnel are retrieved from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics, while exports and GDP data from the World Development Indicators, the World Bank.
Figure 3

Figure 2.3

Figure 4

Figure 2.3

Figure 5

Figure 2.3

Figure 6

Figure 2.3

Figure 7

Figure 2.3

Figure 8

Figure 2.3

Figure 9

Figure 2.3

Figure 10

Figure 2.3

Source: Miguelez et al. (2019).
Figure 11

Figure 2.4 Population density does not ensure high innovation densityPatents and scientific articles in the top thirty-five largest cities, 1980–2016.

Source: WIPO (2019) based on PATSTAT, PCT, and Web of Science data, and top cities from The City Mayors Foundation (September 2019). Notes: Size of bubble refers to the metropolitan area population (circa 2017). Axis in logarithmic scale. Due to low scientific publication or patent values, Kinshasa and Shijiazhuang are omitted from the chart area.
Figure 12

Figure 2.5 Diverging growth pathsReal GDP per capita in 2011US$ (logs), selected economies

Sources: Maddison Project Database, version 2018. Bolt et al. (2018)
Figure 13

Table 2.1 Evolution of patenting and scientific publishing, by selected countries

Source: Miguelez et al. (2019).
Figure 14

Table 2.2 Top innovation-dense Asian agglomerations and national concentration of S&T outputs, 1991–1995 and 2011–2015, selected economies

Source: Miguelez et al. (2019).

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×