Book contents
- Frontmatter
- Dedication
- Contents
- Preface
- List of Contributors
- Dramatis Personae at the end of 1937
- Introduction and Summary
- Part I The roots
- Part II The approach of the Stockholm School
- 4 Expectation and plan: The microeconomics of the Stockholm School
- 5 Sequence analysis and optimization
- 6 There were two Stockholm Schools
- 7 On formal dynamics: From Lundberg to chaos analysis
- 8 Lundberg, Keynes, and the riddles of a general theory
- 9 Macrodynamics and the Stockholm School
- 10 Ohlin and the General Theory
- 11 The monetary economics of the Stockholm School
- 12 The Austrians and the Stockholm School: Two failures in the development of modern macroeconomics?
- 13 The political arithmetics of the Stockholm School
- 14 After the Stockholm School
- Part III The impact of the Stockholm School
- Part IV What remains of the Stockholm School?
- The Stockholm School: A non-Swedish bibliography
4 - Expectation and plan: The microeconomics of the Stockholm School
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 July 2013
- Frontmatter
- Dedication
- Contents
- Preface
- List of Contributors
- Dramatis Personae at the end of 1937
- Introduction and Summary
- Part I The roots
- Part II The approach of the Stockholm School
- 4 Expectation and plan: The microeconomics of the Stockholm School
- 5 Sequence analysis and optimization
- 6 There were two Stockholm Schools
- 7 On formal dynamics: From Lundberg to chaos analysis
- 8 Lundberg, Keynes, and the riddles of a general theory
- 9 Macrodynamics and the Stockholm School
- 10 Ohlin and the General Theory
- 11 The monetary economics of the Stockholm School
- 12 The Austrians and the Stockholm School: Two failures in the development of modern macroeconomics?
- 13 The political arithmetics of the Stockholm School
- 14 After the Stockholm School
- Part III The impact of the Stockholm School
- Part IV What remains of the Stockholm School?
- The Stockholm School: A non-Swedish bibliography
Summary
The Stockholm School had its roots in Knut Wicksell's (1898) macroeconomic analysis of the cumulative process and Gunnar Myrdal's (1927) attempt to extend neoclassical microeconomics (in Gustav Cassel's version) to cover nonstationary phenomena. Both Wicksell's analysis of price level changes and Myrdal's of firm planning in a changing and uncertain environment were attempts to study processes for which comparative statics was an insufficient analytical tool.
The macro- and the microeconomic lines were connected in the twin concepts ex ante and ex post. Starting from the expectations for the future (ex ante), individual firms and households plan their actions for the coming period. The values of the expectation variables registered at the end of the period (ex post) will, however, differ from the expectations held at the beginning of the period. This may result from a lack of coordination between the plans of individual agents or from unexpected external events. The discrepancy between expectations ex ante and outcomes ex post will initiate revisions of both expectations and plans for the coming period. The unexpected – the gap between expectations ex ante and outcomes ex post – is thus one of the factors that drives the system in the period analysis of the Stockholm School (see Lindahl, 1939). The stress on analyzing gaps between plans and expectations on one hand and outcomes on the other reflected the dissociation from equilibrium theory that was a characteristic feature of the Stockholm School.
- Type
- Chapter
- Information
- The Stockholm School of Economics Revisited , pp. 141 - 165Publisher: Cambridge University PressPrint publication year: 1991
- 7
- Cited by