Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T12:43:23.323Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Single-Factor Consumption-Based Asset Pricing Model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 September 2018

Abstract

We propose a single-factor asset pricing model based on an indicator function of consumption growth being less than its endogenous certainty equivalent. This certainty equivalent is derived from generalized disappointment-aversion preferences, and it is located approximately 1 standard deviation below the conditional mean of consumption growth. Our single-factor model can explain the cross section of expected returns for size, value, reversal, profitability, and investment portfolios at least as well as the Fama–French multifactor models. Our results show strong empirical support for asymmetric preferences and question the effectiveness of the smooth utility framework, which is traditionally used in consumption-based asset pricing.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1

We thank Hendrik Bessembinder (the editor) and Lars-Alexander Kuehn (the referee). An earlier version of the article was circulated under the title “One-Factor Asset Pricing.” This article has benefited from the comments of Massimiliano Affinito, Daniele Bianchi, Michael Brennan, Tim Burch, Indraneel Chakraborty, Vidhi Chhaochharia, Ric Colacito, Robert Dittmar, Adam Farago, Andrea Gamba, Gikas Hardouvelis, Alex Horenstein, Petri Jylha, Marcin Kacperczyk, Paul Karehnke, George Korniotis, Roman Kozhan, Alok Kumar, Marie Lambert, Alex Michaelides, David Miles, Paulo Santos Monteiro, Philippe Mueller, Cesare Robotti, Bryan Routledge, Christian Schlag, Maik Schmeling, David Schreindorfer, George Skiadopoulos, Peter Smith, Peter Spencer, Alex Stremme, Roméo Tédongap, John Thanassoulis, Fabio Trojani, Emmanuel Tsiritakis, Raman Uppal, Ansgar Walther, Michael Weber, Mike Wickens, and seminar participants at Imperial College, Inquire UK, the University of Miami, the University of Piraeus, the University of York, the University of Warwick, the 2015 Paris Financial Management Conference, the 2016 Midwest Finance Association (MFA) Annual Meeting, the 2016 Sustainable Architecture for Finance in Europe (SAFE) Asset Pricing Workshop, the 2016 Paris December Finance Meeting, the 2017 Financial Management Association (FMA) Europe Conference, the 2017 Western Finance Association (WFA) Conference, and the 2017 European Finance Association (EFA) Annual Meeting.

References

Ang, A.; Bekaert, G.; and Liu, J.. “Why Stocks May Disappoint.” Journal of Financial Economics, 76 (2005), 471508.Google Scholar
Baker, M., and Wurgler, J.. “Investor Sentiment and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 61 (2006), 16451680.Google Scholar
Barberis, N.; Huang, M.; and Santos, T.. “Prospect Theory and Asset Prices.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (2001), 153.Google Scholar
Boguth, O., and Kuehn, L.-A.. “Consumption Volatility Risk.” Journal of Finance, 68 (2013), 25892615.Google Scholar
Bonomo, M.; Garcia, R.; Meddahi, N.; and Tédongap, R.. “Generalized Disappointment Aversion, Long-Run Volatility Risk, and Asset Prices.” Review of Financial Studies, 24 (2011), 82122.Google Scholar
Breeden, D. T.An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities.” Journal of Financial Economics, 7 (1979), 265296.Google Scholar
Bryzgalova, S.“Spurious Factors in Linear Asset Pricing Models.” Working Paper, Stanford University (2015).Google Scholar
Burnside, C.The Cross-Section of Foreign Currency Risk Premia and Consumption Growth Risk: Comment.” American Economic Review, 101 (2011), 34563476.Google Scholar
Campbell, J.Consumption-Based Asset Pricing.” In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Vol. IB, Constantinides, G. M., Stulz, R. M., and Harris, M., eds. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier (2003).Google Scholar
Choi, S.; Fisman, R.; Gale, D.; and Kariv, S.. “Consistency and Heterogeneity of Individual Behavior under Uncertainty.” American Economic Review, 97 (2007), 19211938.Google Scholar
Cochrane, J. Asset Pricing. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (2001).Google Scholar
Constantinides, G. M.; Jackwerth, J. C.; and Savov, A.. “The Puzzle of Index Option Returns.” Review of Asset Pricing Studies, 3 (2013), 229257.Google Scholar
Dahlquist, M.; Farago, A.; and Tédongap, R.. “Asymmetries and Portfolio Choice.” Review of Financial Studies, 30 (2017), 667702.Google Scholar
De Bondt, W. F., and Thaler, R.. “Does the Stock Market Overreact?Journal of Finance, 40 (1985), 793805.Google Scholar
Delikouras, S.Where’s the Kink? Disappointment Events in Consumption Growth and Equilibrium Asset Prices.” Review of Financial Studies, 30 (2017), 28512889.Google Scholar
Epstein, L. G., and Zin, S. E.. “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns.” Econometrica, 57 (1989), 937969.Google Scholar
Epstein, L. G., and Zin, S. E.. “First-Order Risk Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 26 (1990), 387407.Google Scholar
Epstein, L. G., and Zin, S. E.. “The Independence Axiom and Asset Returns.” Journal of Empirical Finance, 8 (2001), 537572.Google Scholar
Fama, E. F., and French, K. R.. “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics, 33 (1993), 356.Google Scholar
Fama, E. F., and French, K. R.. “A Five-Factor Asset Pricing Model.” Journal of Financial Economics, 116 (2015), 122.Google Scholar
Farago, A., and Tédongap, R.. “Downside Risks and the Cross-Section of Asset Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics, 129 (2018), 6986.Google Scholar
Gill, D., and Prowse, V.. “A Structural Analysis of Disappointment Aversion in a Real Effort Competition.” American Economic Review, 102 (2012), 469503.Google Scholar
Gul, F.A Theory of Disappointment Aversion.” Econometrica, 59 (1991), 667686.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. P.Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators.” Econometrica, 50 (1982), 10291054.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. P., and Singleton, K. J.. “Generalized Instrumental Variables Estimation of Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models.” Econometrica, 50 (1982), 12691286.Google Scholar
Harvey, C. R.; Liu, Y.; and Zhu, H.. “… and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns.” Review of Financial Studies, 29 (2015), 568.Google Scholar
Hou, K.; Xue, C.; and Zhang, L.. “A Comparison of New Factor Models.” Working Paper, Ohio State University (2016).Google Scholar
Jagannathan, R., and Wang, Y.. “Lazy Investors, Discretionary Consumption, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 62 (2007), 16231661.Google Scholar
Jegadeesh, N., and Titman, S.. “Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency.” Journal of Finance, 48 (1993), 6591.Google Scholar
Kocherlakota, N.The Equity Premium: It’s Still a Puzzle.” Journal of Economic Literature, 34 (1996), 4271.Google Scholar
Lakonishok, J.; Shleifer, A.; and Vishny, R. W.. “Contrarian Investment, Extrapolation and Risk.” Journal of Finance, 49 (1994), 15411578.Google Scholar
Lettau, M. L., and Ludvigson, S. C.. “Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 815849.Google Scholar
Lettau, M. L.; Maggiori, M.; and Weber, M.. “Conditional Risk Premia in Currency Markets and Other Asset Classes.” Journal of Financial Economics, 114 (2014), 197225.Google Scholar
Lewellen, J.; Nagel, S.; and Shanken, J.. “A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset Pricing Tests.” Journal of Financial Economics, 96 (2010), 175194.Google Scholar
Liu, L. X.; Whited, T. M.; and Zhang, L.. “Investment-Based Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Political Economy, 117 (2009), 11051139.Google Scholar
Mehra, R., and Prescott, E. C.. “The Equity Premium: A Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 15 (1985), 145161.Google Scholar
Merton, R. C.An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model.” Econometrica, 41 (1973), 867887.Google Scholar
Nozawa, Y.“Corporate Bond Premia.” Working Paper, University of Chicago (2012).Google Scholar
Ostrovnaya, A.; Routledge, B. R.; and Zin, S. E.. “Endogenous Countercyclical Risk Aversion and the Cross-Section.” Working Paper, Carnegie Mellon University (2006).Google Scholar
Parker, J. A., and Julliard, C.. “Consumption Risk and the Cross-Section of Expected Returns.” Journal of Political Economy, 113 (2005), 185222.Google Scholar
Rabin, M.Risk Aversion and Expected-Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem.” Econometrica, 68 (2000), 12811292.Google Scholar
Routledge, B., and Zin, S. E.. “Generalized Disappointment Aversion and Asset Prices.” Journal of Finance, 65 (2010), 13031332.Google Scholar
Savov, A.Asset Pricing with Garbage.” Journal of Finance, 76 (2011), 177201.Google Scholar
Schreindorfer, D.“Tails, Fears, and Equilibrium Option Prices.” Working Paper, Arizona State University (2014).Google Scholar
Segal, U., and Spivak, A.. “First Order versus Second Order Risk Aversion.” Journal of Economic Theory, 51 (1990), 111125.Google Scholar
Welch, I., and Goyal, A.. “A Comprehensive Look at the Empirical Performance of Equity Premium Prediction.” Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2008), 14551508.Google Scholar
Yogo, M.A Consumption-Based Explanation of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 61 (2006), 539580.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Delikouras and Kostakis supplementary material

Delikouras and Kostakis supplementary material 1

Download Delikouras and Kostakis supplementary material(File)
File 571.3 KB