Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T06:24:03.347Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Information, Expected Utility, and Portfolio Choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 August 2010

Jun Liu
Affiliation:
Cheung-Kong Graduate School of Business and Southwestern University of Finance and Economics of China (visiting), on leave from Rady School of Management, University of California at San Diego, 9500 Gilman Dr., La Jolla, CA 92093. junliu@ucsd.edu.
Ehud Peleg
Affiliation:
Anderson School of Management, University of California at Los Angeles, 110 Westwood Plz., Los Angeles, CA 90095. epeleg@anderson.ucla.edu.
Avanidhar Subrahmanyam
Affiliation:
Anderson School of Management, University of California at Los Angeles, 110 Westwood Plz., Los Angeles, CA 90095. subra@anderson.ucla.edu.

Abstract

We study the consumption-investment problem of an agent with a constant relative risk aversion preference function, who possesses noisy information about the future prospects of a stock. We also solve for the value of information to the agent in closed form. We find that information can significantly alter consumption and asset allocation decisions. For reasonable parameter ranges, information increases consumption in the vicinity of 25%. Information can shift the portfolio weight on a stock from 0% to around 70%. Thus, depending on the stock beta, the weight on the market portfolio can be considerably reduced with information, causing the appearance of underdiversification. The model indicates that stock holdings of informed agents are positively related to wealth, unrelated to systematic risk, and negatively related to idiosyncratic uncertainty. We also show that the dollar value of information to the agent depends linearly on his wealth and decreases with both the propensity to intermediate consumption and risk aversion.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Admati, A. R. “A Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multi-Asset Securities Markets.” Econometrica, 53 (1985), 629657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Admati, A. R., and Pfleiderer, P.. “Viable Allocations of Information in Financial Markets.” Journal of Economic Theory, 43 (1987), 76115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Admati, A. R., and Pfleiderer, P.. “A Theory of Intraday Patterns: Volume and Price Variability.” Review of Financial Studies, 1 (1988), 340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Admati, A. R., and Pfleiderer, P.. “Direct and Indirect Sale of Information.” Econometrica, 58 (1990), 901928.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amendinger, J.; Becherer, D.; and Schweizer, M.. “A Monetary Value for Initial Information in Portfolio Optimization.” Finance and Stochastics, 7 (2003), 2946.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ausubel, L. M. “Insider Trading in a Rational Expectations Economy.” American Economic Review, 80 (1990), 10221041.Google Scholar
Back, K. “Insider Trading in Continuous Time.” Review of Financial Studies, 5 (1992), 387409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backus, D. K.; Routledge, B. R.; and Zin, S. E.. “Exotic Preferences for Macroeconomists.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 19 (2004), 319390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baruch, S. “Insider Trading and Risk Aversion.” Journal of Financial Markets, 5 (2002), 451464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhattacharya, U., and Spiegel, M.. “Insiders, Outsiders, and Market Breakdowns.” Review of Financial Studies, 4 (1991), 255282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bitler, M. P.; Moskowitz, T. J.; and Vissing-Jorgensen, A.. “Testing Agency Theory with Entrepreneur Effort and Wealth.” Journal of Finance, 60 (2005), 539576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, M. J., and Cao, H. H.. “International Portfolio Investment Flows.” Journal of Finance, 52 (1997), 18511880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, D. P., and Jennings, R. H.. “On Technical Analysis.” Review of Financial Studies, 2 (1989), 527551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y.; Lettau, M.; Malkiel, B. G.; and Xu, Y.. “Have Individual Stocks Become More Volatile? An Empirical Exploration of Idiosyncratic Risk.” Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. Y.; Lo, A. W.; and MacKinlay, A. C.. The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (1997).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chacko, G., and Viceira, L. M.. “Dynamic Consumption and Portfolio Choice with Stochastic Volatility in Incomplete Markets.” Review of Financial Studies, 18 (2005), 13691402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakravarty, S., and McConnell, J. J.. “Does Insider Trading Really Move Stock Prices?Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 34 (1999), 191209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornell, B., and Sirri, E. R.. “The Reaction of Investors and Stock Prices to Insider Trading.” Journal of Finance, 47 (1992), 10311059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMarzo, P. M.; Kaniel, R.; and Kremer, I.. “Relative Wealth Concerns and Financial Bubbles.” Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2008), 1950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, D. W., and Verrecchia, R. E.. “Information Aggregation in a Noisy Rational Expectations Economy.” Journal of Financial Economics, 9 (1981), 221235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, L. G., and Zin, S. E.. “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework.” Econometrica, 57 (1989), 937969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, L. A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press (1957).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Föllmer, H., and Imkeller, P.. “Anticipation Cancelled by a Girsanov Transformation: A Paradox on Wiener Space.” Annales de l’Institut Henri Poincaré, 29 (1993), 569586.Google Scholar
Foster, F. D., and Viswanathan, S.. “Strategic Trading When Agents Forecast the Forecasts of Others.” Journal of Finance, 51 (1996), 14371478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gompers, P. A., and Metrick, A.. “Institutional Investors and Equity Prices.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (2001), 229259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, S. A., and Stiglitz, J. E.. “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets.” American Economic Review, 70 (1980), 393408.Google Scholar
Grundy, B. D., and McNichols, M.. “Trade and the Revelation of Prices through Direct Disclosure.” Review of Financial Studies, 2 (1989), 495526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadlock, C. J. “Ownership, Liquidity, and Investment.” Rand Journal of Economics, 29 (1998), 487508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellwig, M. F. “On the Aggregation of Information in Competitive Markets.” Journal of Economic Theory, 22 (1980), 477498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holden, C. W., and Subrahmanyam, A.. “Risk Aversion, Imperfect Competition and Long-Lived Information.” Economics Letters, 44 (1994), 181190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hong, H., and Stein, J. C.. “Differences of Opinion, Short-Sales Constraints, and Market Crashes.” Review of Financial Studies, 16 (2003), 487525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacod, J. “Grossisement Initial, Hypothèse (H′), et Thèoréme de Girasnov.” In Grossisements de Filtrations: Exemples et Applications, Jeulin, T. and Yor, M., eds. Berlin: Springer (1985), 1535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. M., and Lamont, O. A.. “Short-Sale Constraints and Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics, 66 (2002), 207239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahl, M.; Liu, J.; and Longstaff, F. A.. “Paper Millionaires: How Valuable Is a Stock to a Stockholder Who Is Restricted from Selling It?Journal of Financial Economics, 67 (2003), 385410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kang, J.-K., and Stulz, R. M.. “Why Is There a Home Bias? An Analysis of Foreign Portfolio Equity Ownership in Japan.” Journal of Financial Economics, 46 (1997), 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, T. S., and Omberg, E.. “Dynamic Nonmyopic Portfolio Behavior.” Review of Financial Studies, 9 (1996), 141161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M., and Porteus, E. L.. “Temporal Resolution of Uncertainty and Dynamic Choice Theory.” Econometrica, 46 (1978), 185200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kyle, A. S. “Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading.” Econometrica, 53 (1985), 13151335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leland, H. “Insider Trading: Should It Be Prohibited?Journal of Political Economy, 100 (1992), 859887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, J., and Longstaff, F. A.. “Losing Money on Arbitrage: Optimal Dynamic Portfolio Choice in Markets with Arbitrage Opportunities.” Review of Financial Studies, 17 (2004), 611641.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manove, M. “The Harm from Insider Trading and Informed Speculation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104 (1989), 823845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehra, R., and Prescott, E.. “The Equity Premium: A Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 15 (1985), 145161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R. C. “Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model.” Journal of Economic Theory, 3 (1971), 373413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meulbroek, L. K. “An Empirical Analysis of Illegal Insider Trading.” Journal of Finance, 47 (1992), 16611699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morse, A., and Shive, S.. “Patriotism in Your Portfolio.” Journal of Financial Markets, forthcoming (2010).Google Scholar
Moskowitz, T. J., and Vissing-Jorgensen, A.. “The Returns to Entrepreneurial Investment: A Private Equity Premium Puzzle?American Economic Review, 92 (2002), 745778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ofek, E., and Richardson, M.. “DotCom Mania: The Rise and Fall of Internet Stock Prices.” Journal of Finance, 58 (2003), 11131137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peress, J. “Wealth, Information Acquisition and Portfolio Choice.” Review of Financial Studies, 17 (2004), 879914.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pikovsky, I., and Karatzas, I.. “Anticipative Portfolio Optimization.” Advances in Applied Probability, 28 (1996), 10951122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozeff, M. S., and Zaman, M. A.. “Market-Efficiency and Insider Trading: New Evidence.” Journal of Business, 61 (1988), 2544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schweizer, K.; Beck-Seyffer, A.; and Schneider, R.. “Cognitive Bias of Optimism and Its Influence on Psychological Well-Being.” Psychological Reports, 84 (1999), 627636.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seyhun, H. N. “Insiders’ Profits, Costs of Trading, and Market Efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics, 16 (1986), 189212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seyhun, H. N. “Why Does Aggregate Insider Trading Predict Future Stock Returns?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107 (1992), 13031331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegel, J. J. Stocks for the Long Run (2nd ed.). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill Publishers (1998).Google Scholar
Subrahmanyam, A. “Risk Aversion, Market Liquidity, and Price Efficiency.” Review of Financial Studies, 4 (1991), 417441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlenbeck, G. E., and Ornstein, L. S.. “On the Theory of the Brownian Motion.” Physical Review, 36 (1930), 823841.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verrecchia, R. E. “Information Acquisition in a Noisy Rational Expectations Economy.” Econometrica, 50 (1982), 14151430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vives, X. “Short-Term Investment and the Informational Efficiency of the Market.” Review of Financial Studies, 8 (1995), 125170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, J. “A Model of Intertemporal Asset Prices Under Asymmetric Information.” Review of Economic Studies, 60 (1993), 249282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar