Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T01:34:41.793Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political Mandate and Clarity of Responsibility: Economic Policies under Rightist Governments in Latin America

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2018

Glen Biglaiser*
Affiliation:
University of North Texas, US
Ronald J. McGauvran
Affiliation:
Tennessee Tech University, US
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Since the mid-1990s, some rightist governments in Latin America have adhered to a strict market orientation while others have shown less attachment to doctrinaire neoliberal policies, a puzzle as rightists are expected to favor minimal government intervention in the economy. In an environment over the past two decades in which market-oriented policies, in general, have grown increasingly unpopular with many Latin Americans, we contend that rightists have less political cover to endorse neoliberal policies. Using panel data for eighteen Latin American countries from 1995 to 2015, we find that, because of the clarity of responsibility that occurs under political mandates and the unpopularity of market reforms, mandate-holding rightist governments will tend to go against their ideological preferences and decrease neoliberal policies. Our findings indicate that as presidential vote margins increase and responsibility for unpopular economic policies becomes clearer, rightist executives will be less willing to support such policies, but only to a point. The results suggest that clarity of responsibility can influence presidential decision-making concerning unpopular policies, especially microeconomic policies, but this influence diminishes as presidents become more electorally secure.

A partir de mediados de la década de los 90, algunos gobiernos latinoamericanos de derecha han adoptado políticas estrictas de apertura comercial, mientras que otros se han mostrado más alejados de adoptar políticas neoliberales. Esto es un elemento relevante de análisis ya que se espera que los gobiernos de derecha estén en contra de la intervención del gobierno en la economía. Usando una base de datos panel sobre 18 países latinoamericanos para el periodo de 1995 a 2015, encontramos que los gobiernos de derecha actúan en contra de sus preferencias ideológicas disminuyendo políticas neoliberales por dos razones: la claridad que los mandatarios tienen sobre sus responsabilidades y la impopularidad de las reformas de libre mercado en Latinoamérica. Nuestros hallazgos indican que, si el margen de votos en las elecciones presidenciales incrementa y el sentido de responsabilidad sobre la adopción de políticas económicas impopulares es claro, los gobernantes de derecha estarán menos dispuestos a adoptar este tipo de políticas de libre mercado.

Type
Politics and International Relations
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (CC-BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. See http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
Copyright
Copyright: © 2018 The Author(s)

Since the late 1990s, many studies have investigated the economic policies of leftist governments in Latin America.Footnote 1 Much of the interest derives from the stark differences in policies ranging from maintaining, and even intensifying, market-oriented reforms, to expanding the role of the state in the economy. Missing largely from the literature is the economic policies under rightist governments in Latin America.Footnote 2 Much like the left, not all rightists have followed the same policies. Although some rightist governments have adhered to a strict neoliberal model, others have shown less doctrinaire attachment to market reforms, which is puzzling since rightists have traditionally favored minimal government intervention in the economy.

Political economists have developed a litany of theories to explain economic policies under leftist governments that also appear applicable to rightist regimes. Among the theories, some studies stress party institutionalization, contending that high party institutionalization promotes interparty and interbranch cooperation, encouraging presidents to maintain status-quo, market-oriented policies (Reference Flores-MacíasFlores-Macías 2010, Reference Flores-Macías2012; Reference Levitsky, Roberts, Levitsky and RobertsLevitsky and Roberts 2011). Others suggest that the boom in industries and commodities tied to production for the global market has generated greater export-oriented influence in domestic labor markets, increasing the probability for market reforms (Reference FriedenFrieden 1991; Reference RemmerRemmer 1998). Additionally, factor endowment research indicates that countries abundant in natural resources support interventionist policies because the state typically controls resource sectors, providing politicians with the financial means to placate popular interests (Reference WeylandWeyland 2009; Reference HidalgoHidalgo 2009). This article will focus on the importance of political mandates. Although previous research has shown that leaders holding mandates have greater discretion to implement their preferred policies (Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016; Reference Johnson and CrispJohnson and Crisp 2003),Footnote 3 we have reason to believe that this discretion is limited, especially when many of the economic policies are not particularly popular with the general populace.

Using panel data for up to eighteen Latin American countries from 1995 until 2015, we find support for the mandate theory but in a way largely unpredicted for rightist rule. The scholarly literature suggests that rightist presidents favor neoliberalism, including a limited role for the state to address economic inequality, because their richer core constituencies benefit from market policies (Reference GibsonGibson 1996; Reference Luna and Rovira KaltwasserLuna and Rovira Kaltwasser 2014; Reference MiddlebrookMiddlebrook 2000, 3–4; Reference Wiesehomeier and BenoitWiesehomeier and Benoit 2009).Footnote 4 Given their preference for market reforms and the enhanced policy discretion that comes with a mandate, practitioners of mandate theory would expect rightist leaders to back neoliberal policies. However, we argue that because of the clarity of responsibility that arises between mandate holders and the electorate, rightist presidents experience cross pressures that often make them less likely to uphold the most strict market policies as compared to governments that lack mandates.Footnote 5

With regard to cross pressures, on the one hand, the advance of leftist governments in power since the late 1990s has forced the right, for electability reasons, to moderate the most orthodox neoliberal policies introduced in the late 1980s and early 1990s. The right realizes that, with the exception of trade liberalization (Reference BakerBaker 2003; Reference Baker and GreeneBaker and Greene 2011), orthodox market reforms have grown less popular with many Latin Americans over the past two decades, calling into question the “political viability of the neoliberal model” (Reference Roberts, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserRoberts 2014, 25). Indeed, one reason for the electoral success of left parties since the late 1990s has been their willingness to moderate or even abandon the most extreme neoliberal reforms.Footnote 6 On the other hand, rightist governments recognize the challenges of breaking with market-oriented reforms, particularly macro-level policies, that places them at odds with global policy-making circles (Reference Luna and Rovira KaltwasserLuna and Rovira Kaltwasser 2014, 16; Reference Roberts, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserRoberts 2014, 26). Rightist leaders understand that moving completely away from neoliberalism could shut them out of foreign capital markets and increase foreign capital flight. Moreover, an influential minority of rightist constituents strongly favor market reforms. Thus, rightist governments are cross-pressured, attempting to maintain market reforms to appease the global economy and a minority of its constituents while retaining enough domestic political support to win, or remain in, office.

We argue that the pressures to serve the broader electorate, and the electoral consequences of supporting less popular policies, are greater for mandate-holding rightists—who have greater clarity of responsibility, defined by unified government and presidential margin of victory—making them less prone to sustain the strictest market reforms. Unlike under divided government, where the different parties often blame each other for maintaining an orthodox neoliberal model, the parties still support the reforms because they satisfy the investment community, while clarity of responsibility fostered by a mandate informs voters as to who is responsible for the unpopular neoliberal policies (Reference Powell and WhittenPowell and Whitten 1993, 398). The large number of voters opposing strict market reforms results in mandate holders moderating doctrinaire neoliberal reforms, especially micro-level economic policies, because of global financial markets tendency to exert macroeconomic discipline in developing countries (Reference KaplanKaplan 2013; Reference MahonMahon 1996; Reference MosleyMosley 2003; Reference WibbelsWibbels 2006). Although we expect there are limits on clarity of responsibility, we contend that rightist leaders holding mandates will call greater attention to more popular measures that reflect the right party’s strengths including managing public order and security, pledging support for conservative social policies, and promoting government programs serving the very poor, all as means to win elections and stay in office (Reference Meléndez, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserMeléndez 2014; Reference Koivumaeki, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserKoivumaeki 2014; Reference Wiesehomeier, Doyle, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserWiesehomeier and Doyle 2014).

This project contributes to the literature in several ways. First, this study provides new insights for understanding economic policies under rightist administrations in Latin America, an area understudied in the literature.Footnote 7 Second, the findings complement a range of political economy research showing a schism between adherence to macro- and micro-level economic policies (Reference BoixBoix 1998; Reference MurilloMurillo 2009; Reference KaplanKaplan 2013). Third, and most importantly, the research explains why mandate-holding executives from the right appear to go against their presumed ideological preferences, helping to solve a puzzle in the literature.

Theories on Economic Policies under Rightist Governments in Latin America

Since the late 1980s and early 1990s, nearly all Latin American countries abandoned import-substitution industrialization (ISI) and adopted orthodox neoliberal reforms. The swing to a market orientation seemed consistent with the ideology historically held by many rightist parties in Latin America. The Conservative Party in Chile under President Jorge Alessandri in 1958–1964 typified the view held by much of the Latin American right during the post–World War II era, preferring the market to state intervention. Moreover, the fact that many rightist parties took office in the late 1980s and early 1990s and played central roles in initiating neoliberal reforms, further bolstered connections between market reforms and the right (Reference MiddlebrookMiddlebrook 2000, 46–47). Lastly, survey work conducted by Wiesehomeier and Benoit (Reference Wiesehomeier and Benoit2009) also appears to show the strong market orientation of the right. Wiesehomeier and Benoit (Reference Wiesehomeier and Benoit2009) asked experts to assess the policy positions of different political parties and party leaders (including current presidents) in eighteen Latin American countries. Experts placed parties and presidents on a 1–20 scale, with higher scores on economic issues reflecting greater backing for the market. The survey results indicated that rightist parties and their leaders in all eighteen countries scored above 10 in support of globalization. Similarly, rightist parties and their leaders favored cutting public services to reduce taxes rather than raising taxes to increase public services in sixteen of the eighteen countries.Footnote 8

Despite the many factors suggesting that rightist governments should favor a market strategy, economic policies have varied under rightist administrations. Some parties have tended to back the status quo, maintaining or even expanding on market-oriented reforms, while others have been less doctrinaire in their support for the neoliberal model. Differences among rightist governments present a puzzle in the political economy literature that has received limited scholarly attention. We propose a theory that seeks to explain the conditions in which rightest governments in Latin America would move away from their ideological preference on neoliberal economic reforms and implement less market-oriented policies. Our theory indicates that political mandates for rightest governments produce a cross-pressured environment where mandates allow them to enact their preferred policies more freely while making the responsibilities for those policies more clear. We argue that when neoliberal policies appear less popular, political mandates can actually make it harder to enact such policies due to potential blame attribution. Even in situations of improved economic performance, the fact that neoliberal reforms have tended to exacerbate economic inequality may contribute to more moderating policies that seeks greater economic redistribution.Footnote 9

The basis for our theory evolves from the literature, showing how political mandates can affect the policies that governments implement (Reference Grossback, Peterson and StimsonGrossback, Peterson, and Stimson 2007; Reference Johnson and CrispJohnson and Crisp 2003; Reference LightLight 1989, 26; Reference Mainwaring and ShugartMainwaring and Shugart 1997). A political mandate, as indicated by a landslide presidential victory (Reference ConleyConley 2001; Reference JonesJones 1999) and the executive’s party holding a majority of seats in the legislature (Reference Weinbaum and JuddWeinbaum and Judd 1970), creates the conditions necessary for presidents to install their preferred policies (Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016; Reference Mainwaring and ShugartMainwaring and Shugart 1997). Political mandate theory would anticipate that, because of their ideological preferences, rightist executives favor neoliberal reforms (Reference GibsonGibson 1996; Reference MiddlebrookMiddlebrook 2000).

Building on research on clarity of responsibility, we present a nuanced version of what political mandate theory would predict for rightist governments and market policies. Before developing the argument, we first develop the concept of clarity of responsibility. Clarity of responsibility dates back to the work of Powell and Whitten (Reference Powell and Whitten1993), who argued that a voter’s assignment of responsibility depends largely on the coherence and control government exerts over policy. Unlike in political systems with divided government, where the executive and majority in the legislature come from different parties—or in cases where the president won office in a close race and voters may not know who to credit (or blame) for economic policies, the legislative or executive branch—a mandate suggests unified control of policymaking as the government comes from the same party (Reference Powell and WhittenPowell and Whitten 1993, 398).

Beyond the importance of mandates for assigning responsibility, clarity of responsibility matters most during periods of economic crises, as voters can observe shocks to the macroeconomy and assign blame (Reference Duch and StevensonDuch and Stevenson 2008). Although there has been some variation in economic performance among countries in the region (see Reference KaplanKaplan 2013), Latin America has experienced numerous economic crises in most countries over the past two decades. The high frequency of economic crises across much of the region increases the chance that clarity of responsibility resonates with both Latin American leaders and voters.

Complementing the work of Duch and Stevenson (Reference Duch and Stevenson2008), and Powell and Whitten (Reference Powell and Whitten1993), we contend that clarity of responsibility affects the policies of mandate-holding rightists. The logic of the argument is that in attempting to serve constituents as well as protect the interests of the global (and domestic) financial community, leaders on the right frequently face cross pressures and will give more support to their broader constituent base by moderating neoliberal policies at the minor expense of the financial community and a small number of influential rightist backers. On the one hand, right parties need to support the interests of constituents, many of whom question the benefits of most orthodox neoliberal policies. Survey data conducted by the polling service Latinobarómetro between 2002 and 2009 indicate fairly strong public disapproval for market policies in all Latin American countries. In a question about satisfaction with the functioning of the market economy, on average, less than 27 percent of responses expressed satisfaction with the operation of the market while more than 73 percent responded not very satisfied, not at all satisfied, don’t know, or no answer to the question (see Table 1).Footnote 10

Table 1 Percent saying they are very (or rather) satisfied with the functioning of the market economy in the country.

Source: Latinobarómetro: http://www.latinobarometro.org/latCodebooks.jsp.

n.a. = not available.

Many Latin Americans also have been deeply critical of privatization, a fundamental component of neoliberal models. In a Latinobarómetro survey conducted between 1998 and 2009 asking whether privatization of state companies has been beneficial, less than 35 percent, on average, agreed or strongly agreed about the merits of privatization (see Table 2). As much as any economic reform, privatization draws intense domestic protest tied to concerns over sovereignty, unemployment, and regulation (Reference Roberts and ArceRoberts and Arce 1998). But privatization is not the only policy that unleashes public harangues. Indeed, with the exception of trade openness, support for the neoliberal model has fallen throughout Latin America (Reference BakerBaker 2003; Reference Baker and GreeneBaker and Greene 2011).Footnote 11

Table 2 Percent agreeing or strongly agreeing with the statement: The privatization of state companies has been beneficial to the country.

Source: Latinobarómetro: http://www.latinobarometro.org/latCodebooks.jsp.

n.a. = not available.

Ironically, previous research suggested that Latin American politicians initiated orthodox market reforms in the 1990s, often breaking promises in political campaigns to support greater state intervention, because elected officials calculated that such reforms would benefit their constituents and ultimately would serve their own political ambitions (Reference StokesStokes 2001).Footnote 12 As many Latin American politicians have since discovered and polling information suggests, following a rigid neoliberal course may backfire for survival-minded leaders (Reference MadridMadrid 2010; Reference RobertsRoberts 2012). Rightist politicians cannot rely on a minority of rightist constituents who fully embrace the most orthodox neoliberal model if they hope to succeed electorally. On the other hand, most rightist executives and their parties recognize that in an integrated global economy, as Latin American countries have operated under for more than two decades, politicians need to maintain some measure of market reforms or they will confront economic challenges from the international (and domestic) financial community (Reference Luna and Rovira KaltwasserLuna and Rovira Kaltwasser 2014, 16; Reference Roberts, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserRoberts 2014, 26). There is, of course, liable to be variation in the degree of market openness countries will uphold, which we will discuss later, but the point is that the global financial community imposes constraints on economic policies. Most leaders realize that disregarding the interests of the global financial community and overturning neoliberal policies risks their countries losing access to desperately needed foreign capital markets.

We contend that clarity of responsibility that comes with a mandate and general dissatisfaction with most market reforms increases the probability that mandate-holding rightists will moderate from their presumed preferences and the interests of the investment community and support a less doctrinaire neoliberal model. Because mandate holders from the right likely would be held accountable if they maintained or amplified orthodox market policies, such governments have tended to downplay neoliberal policies and have focused on their perceived strengths tied to public order and security, conservative social issues, and pro-poor policies, measures favorably received by most of their constituents. Although mandates provide presidents with greater discretion to institute their preferred policies, mandates also enhance clarity of responsibility between voters and elected officials that compel presidents to follow voter demands, in this case softening neoliberal policies.

However, we expect the more moderate neoliberal stance will have greater impact on micro-level economic policies as compared to macro-level policies. Based on literature for the developing world, the financial community particularly opposes changes at the macro level. Foreign investors rail against macro-level reforms that restrict trade openness, increase government deficit spending, and raise levels of inflation and price controls, as such policies have the most effect on their economic bottom line (Reference KaplanKaplan 2013; Reference MahonMahon 1996; Reference MosleyMosley 2003; Reference WibbelsWibbels 2006). Because foreign investors likely will respond with large capital flight against governments that institute macro-level policy changes, mandate holders will tend to uphold macro-level reforms. Instead, rightist governments have leaned toward more moderate micro-level economic policies, including labor and business reforms. By instituting micro-level changes such as wage increases and higher regulations on starting new businesses, the governments can gain support from labor interests and already established businesses, which may favor restrictions that reduce competition from potential newcomers while imposing minimal damage on global finance.

In situations where rightist executives do not hold a mandate, such as in minority governments, coalitions, or a bicameral opposition, we maintain that blame (or responsibility) for policies is harder to assign to presidents or the party in power. The fact that voters cannot clearly apportion responsibility for policies to non-mandate-holding governments provides politicians with increased political cover to maintain stricter market reforms. Politicians from both the left and right often have incentives to support such reforms because they placate the investment community, an important group for creating jobs and whose supporters frequently contribute to political campaigns on both sides of the aisle.Footnote 13

However, we do not believe that the moderating effect of clarity of responsibility on the enactment of neoliberal policies is unlimited. Research on clarity of responsibility asserts that as assignment of responsibility for policies becomes easier, political actors face greater electoral consequences for enacting unpopular policies (Reference Powell and WhittenPowell and Whitten 1993). This assertion is at odds with the mandate literature, which indicates that greater electoral margins insulate political actors from electoral vulnerability and allow politicians to use more discretion (Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016). Our theory seeks to unify these seemly disparate theories by showing that clarity of responsibility can mitigate the discretionary power of political mandates, but only to a point. When mandates reach a size necessary to reduce electoral vulnerability, the mitigating effects of clarity of responsibility will cease. Therefore, we expect that Latin American presidents with political mandates will support more moderate neoliberal policies as clarity of responsibility increases, but as their mandates increase, and their positions become less vulnerable, they will revert to their support of more orthodox neoliberal economic policies. Rightest governments thus enact greater neoliberal market reforms, when such reforms are fairly unpopular, under two conditions: when the election is close enough to cloud the clarity of responsibility, and when the margin of victory is so great that the executives are seemingly impervious to political challenges.

Based on work related to political mandates and clarity of responsibility, we propose the following hypotheses:

  • H1: Increases in presidential margins of victory for rightest executives will decrease the likelihood of implementation of strict market-oriented policies.

  • H2: The effect of margin of victory on the likelihood of implementation of strict market-oriented policies will be curvilinear and eventually become positive.

  • H3: Unified government for rightist executives will decrease the likelihood of implementation of strict market-oriented policies.

  • H4: Presidential mandates and clarity of responsibility are more likely to affect micro-level economic policies rather than macro-level policies.

Research Design and Methods

We collected annual data for up to eighteen presidential democracies in Latin America from 1995–2015 (see the online supplementary Appendix for the list of countries and years of the administrations). We code the country’s governing parties as either right/right-center, center, left-center/left, using a consensus method that compares ideological placements from multiple sources. We combine ideological placements from World Bank’s Database of Political Institutions (Reference Beck, Clarke, Groff, Keefer and WalshBeck et al. 2001)Footnote 14 as well as placements from Doyle (Reference Doyle2012), Pop-Eleches (Reference Pop-Eleches2009), and Baker and Greene (Reference Baker and Greene2011). We use the four independent measures developed by the authors to arrive at a consensus on the ideology of the government. For each observation there was a placement reached by a majority of the sources, which provides us confidence that the regimes are appropriately classified. For the purposes of establishing the effects of mandates on rightists’ economic policies, we run separate sets of models for only rightist executives, rightist and centrist executives, and finally a model which includes the entire ideological spectrum.

The primary dependent variable for this analysis is the Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom. The index includes ten economic freedoms most associated with market reforms: property rights protection, freedom from corruption, fiscal freedom, labor freedom, government spending, business freedom, monetary freedom, trade freedom, investment freedom, and financial freedom. The index uses sources from multiple organizations including the Economist Intelligence Unit, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank, and the US Department of State to determine the value for each freedom.Footnote 15 The index has been called on by many previous studies (Reference Barro, Miller, Holmes and FeulnerBarro 2013; Reference Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt and LevineBeck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine 2006; Reference Lee, Biglaiser and StaatsLee, Biglaiser, and Staats 2014; Reference Roberts, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserRoberts 2014, 41).Footnote 16 We also test our hypotheses on each of the ten component measures of the index to determine if the effects of mandates are uniform across the measures. Each economic freedom is graded on a scale from 0 to 100, with higher numbers indicating a greater market orientation. A country’s score is a weighted average of the ten economic freedom indexes.

The primary independent variables, comprising previous operationalizations of political mandates, are unified government, and presidential margin of victory. Executives possess unified governments when their parties hold absolute majorities in their houses that have lawmaking powers. In the case of a bicameral legislature, executive parties must have a majority in both houses.Footnote 17 We measure presidential margin of victory as the difference in the vote percentage received between the current president and the closest challenger in the most recent election. We coded presidential margin from the ultimate round, as some elections required a second round; in these cases, a dummy variable for second round is included. Presidential and legislative electoral data come from Adam-Carr.net and the Parline database on national parliaments (http://www.ipu.org/parline-e/parlinesearch.asp). Since a presidential mandate comprises both of these variables, we employ an interaction term between presidential margin of victory and unified government. Additionally, since we contend that the effects of a mandate are curvilinear, we include a squared presidential margin of victory term.

Latin America has seen left parties become increasingly popular, with almost all countries having elected a leftist president in the last decade (Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016). With left parties becoming more popular, there is some reason to believe that parties on the far right may be receiving smaller electoral margins, and therefore our mandate measure could be picking up unobserved ideology effects, which explain policy outcomes. We thus include a measure of ideology, used in previous research on mandates (Reference Baker and GreeneBaker and Greene 2011), which is a score on a continuous 0–20 scale with 0 coded as extreme left and 20 being extreme right.Footnote 18

We also control for alternative explanations that could account for strict market-oriented policies. Many studies have investigated the effect of party institutionalization on differences in policies, maintaining that countries with institutionalized party systems are more likely to retain market status-quo policies (Reference Flores-MacíasFlores-Macías 2010, Reference Flores-Macías2012; Reference MainwaringMainwaring 2006; Reference Kaufman, Levitsky and RobertsKaufman 2011). We control for party institutionalization by including electoral volatility, a common proxy for party institutionalization, because low electoral volatility and high party institutionalization tend to go together (Reference Flores-MacíasFlores-Macías 2010, Reference Flores-Macías2012). We utilize electoral volatility developed by Pedersen (Reference Pedersen1979), which is exactly one-half of the net change in the percentage of votes won by parties from the previous legislative election. We also include a measure of presidential duration to test whether the length of tenure has an effect on enacting market-oriented policies.

The boom in industries and commodities tied to production for the global market, along with the collapse of most firms geared toward ISI since the late 1980s, has generated greater export-oriented influence in domestic labor markets (Reference MurilloMurillo 2000; Reference Wibbels and ArceWibbels and Arce 2003). Because of their increasing influence, export-oriented interests are successful in lobbying politicians, who, in turn, support more extensive, market-oriented reforms (Reference FriedenFrieden 1991; Reference RemmerRemmer 1998). To address the growth of trade-oriented industries in influencing economic policies, we control for the export sector using a measure of exports as a percentage of GDP.

Other researchers contend that country natural resource endowments influence policies. Specifically, countries that derive much of their revenues from natural resources favor statist policies, as the abundant proceeds earned from resource exports, often under the control of the public sector, give political leaders added financial flexibility to benefit larger segments of the populace (Reference WeylandWeyland 2009; Reference HidalgoHidalgo 2009). For testing the natural resource endowment argument, we add annual ores and metals exports (as a percent of merchandise exports) to fuel exports (as a percent of merchandise exports), a measure used in the political economy literature (Reference JensenJensen 2003). We also include economic controls for annual GDP growth and logged GDP per capita (2005 U.S. dollars), which address possible economic situations and crises experienced by individual countries.Footnote 19 All economic data come from the World Bank (2015).

International factors including international organizations and trends also potentially affect economic policy. Researchers have found that when countries enter into agreements with the IMF, as many Latin American governments have, they are frequently required to enact policies that are contrary to their interests and are often detrimental to economic growth (Reference DreherDreher 2006; Reference StiglitzStiglitz 2002; Reference VreelandVreeland 2003). Indeed, as we note in our theoretical discussion of political mandates, financial markets tend to impose pressures on developing countries to support more open markets. We control for IMF conditionality with a dummy variable for countries currently under an IMF extended fund facility or stand-by agreement, as these arrangements come with strict loan conditions (Reference Biglaiser and DeRouenBiglaiser and DeRouen 2010). Additionally, global capital mobility can affect neoliberal economic policies. Mosley (Reference Mosley2003) finds that, in the developing world, financial markets exert a considerable influence on government policy. To control for global capital mobility, we include the Chinn-Ito Index (2008), which is a measure of financial capital openness. This measure has been used in previous research on Latin America as a proxy for global capital mobility (Reference De la Torre, Ize and SchmuklerDe la Torre, Ize, and Schmukler 2011; Reference Huber and StephensHuber and Stephens 2012). We also include decade dummy variables to ensure that our findings are not a result of decade differences. All independent variables are lagged a year.

For the analysis, we employ a panel data approach that accounts for the unbalanced nature of our time series. Specifically, we use a fixed effects generalized least squares (GLS) procedure employing weighted least squares that can handle a wide range of unequally spaced panel data patterns (Reference Baltagi and WuBaltagi and Wu 1999). This approach allows for the estimation of unequally spaced panel data and provides natural estimates of the serial correlation and variance components parameter, while still accounting for the AR(1) disturbances. The Wooldridge test for unit-specific first order autoregressive AR(1) process in the panel data calculated a probability of F > 0.000, which rejects the null hypothesis of no first-order autocorrelation. Additionally, since we are examining the effects of within-country change in neoliberal economic policies, we include country- and year-specific fixed effects. The Hausman specification test indicated that the model was best fit by a fixed effects structure with a probability over the chi2 distribution > 0.000.

Results

We begin to present the results of our analysis in Table 3. Models 1–3 examine the effects of mandates and clarity of responsibility on right and center-right parties, Models 4–6 include center parties, and Model 7 examines the entire ideological spectrum. Looking at Models 1 and 2, we find that our mandate variables have a statistically significant effect at the p < 0.01 level, with unified government having a positive relationship, and presidential margins having a negative relationship. This indicates that countries with unified government are more likely, and countries with greater presidential margins less likely, to promote the most strict market-oriented reforms. This finding offers support for Hypothesis 1, but not Hypothesis 2, while the statistically significant relationship found for the squared term indicates support for Hypothesis 2. Model 2, which tests the interactive relationship between our mandate variables, provides clearer evidence of our expected relationship. Model 2 supports our expectations that unified government and presidential margins are conditional on each other, with the effect of each being affected by the value of the other.

Table 3 Political mandate and market reforms in Latin America.

Dependent variable: Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom (Overall Score). All independent variables lagged 1 year. All regressions include country and year fixed effects.

Significance level: * p < .1; ** p < .05; *** p < .01.

Due to the difficulty of interpreting interactive relationships from regression coefficients, Figure 1 presents the findings from Model 2 graphically. Figure 1 indicates, consistent with Hypotheses 1 and 2, that the effects of presidential margins of victory are negative and curvilinear. Initial increases in the presidential margin of victory, which produces greater clarity of responsibility, results in an expected decrease in the likelihood that right presidents will promote the strictest market-oriented reforms. However, this effect is not continuous across the entire spectrum of margin of victory. Figure 1 indicates that once the presidential margin of victory surpasses about 25 percent, increasing presidential margins produce greater likelihood of the implementation of the strictest market-oriented reforms. This finding is consistent with our theory since clarity of responsibility will reduce the likelihood of implementation of unpopular policies insofar as presidents face electoral vulnerability. Once a president’s margin of victory becomes large enough to produce a safe electoral position, the negative effects of clarity of responsibility on the implementation of preferred policy should dissipate, which is what we find.

Figure 1 Effects of unified government and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores.

Inconsistent with Hypothesis 3, Model 3 indicates that presidents with unified government are actually more likely to promote the strictest market-oriented reforms. However, the initial negative effects of presidential margin of victory is stronger for presidents with unified government. This finding indicates that right presidents with unified governments are actually more vulnerable to clarity of responsibility, though this effect also dissipates once these presidents are less vulnerable to electoral challenge. Together this indicates that right presidents with unified government are more vulnerable to clarity of responsibility, however, they are also more likely to implement strict market-oriented policies.

Model 3 presents the results from our analysis where presidential mandate is interacted with the president’s ideology score on a left-to-right-spectrum. Figure 2 presents the results graphically and indicates that extreme-right presidents, with a predicted ideological score of 18, are less likely to implement market-oriented reforms as presidential margin of victory increases, indicating that they are more vulnerable to clarity of responsibility than center-right presidents are. Center-right presidents, with a predicted ideological score of 12, increase the likelihood of implementing market-oriented reforms, which is more consistent with the previous research on mandates (Reference Johnson and CrispJohnson and Crisp 2003; Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016). Additionally, we find that the presidential margin necessary for increasing the likelihood of producing greater market-oriented reforms is greater for extreme-right presidents (31 percent), than it is for center-right presidents (9 percent). The results bolster our argument that clarity of responsibility carries the most weight with politicians farthest to the right, who ideologically should be most committed to neoliberal policies, but who are more vulnerable electorally to upholding market reforms.

Figure 2 Effects of right party ideology and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores.

Looking now at the controls, we find that electoral volatility has a positive and significant expected effect on the implementation of market-oriented reforms, which may indicate that political volatility could be making clarity of responsibility harder. When support for political parties change quickly, and increasing segments of the population move support from one party to another, correctly identifying which party is responsible for the enactment of unpopular policies becomes more difficult. Voters find it increasingly difficult to indicate which party is responsible for unpopular policies after only a few years (Reference Johnson and RyuJohnson and Ryu 2010); this makes clarity of responsibility more challenging, and perceptive politicians know this. We also find support for the natural resource endowment argument. The negative and statistically significant relationship for natural resource endowment indicates that countries with greater natural resource wealth are less likely to implement market-oriented reforms.

Models 4–6 indicate that the effects found for right presidents also hold once center party governments are included. Presidential margin has a negative and significant relationship with the likelihood that market-oriented policies are enacted, though that relationship is again curvilinear and becomes positive after a significant interval, which provides further support to Hypotheses 1 and 2. Unified government produces a greater likelihood of enacting market-oriented policies, but the negative effect of increasing presidential margins is greater for unified government, which indicates split support for Hypothesis 3. Additionally, we test our hypotheses across the full ideological spectrum and find similar results for right parties. The effect of presidential margin of victory is initially negative but curvilinear, and unified governments are slightly more likely to implement market-oriented policies, though the results are less robust than the model for only right parties. A graphical representation of the findings, similar to Figure 1, is presented in Appendix Figure A2.

Table 4 presents the results for the models, which examine the effects of mandates and clarity of responsibility, on the component parts of the Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom. We generally find support for our theory and Hypothesis 4 concerning presidential mandates and clarity of responsibility on micro-level economic policies rather than macro-level policies. We find that rightist leaders holding mandates tend to moderate micro-level policies including business freedom (e.g., starting and closing a business), labor freedom (e.g., wages and labor rigidities), property rights (e.g., laws enforced by the state that guarantee the ability of individuals to acquire private property), freedom from corruption, financial freedom (e.g., government regulation of financial services), fiscal freedom (e.g., individual and corporate tax policies), and investment freedoms, while most macro-level policies do not have a statistically significant relationship. Moreover, as shown in Figure 3, macro-level policies including government spending and monetary freedom (e.g., inflation and price controls) have nearly straight lines, and for trade freedom (e.g., tariff rates and non-tariff barriers) the slopes of the curves are fairly shallow. In contrast, with the exception of financial freedom, the lines are highly curvilinear for micro-level policies. The statistically significant relationships found from the models of the constituent indices and the graphs are largely consistent with our theory that presidential mandates and clarity of responsibility have important effects on moderating neoliberal policies, and particularly for micro-level economic policies.

Table 4 Political mandate and market reforms in Latin America for right parties.

Dependent variable: Heritage Foundation’s Index of Economic Freedom (components). All independent variables lagged 1 year. All regressions include country and year fixed effects.

Significance level: *p < .1; **p < .05; ****p < .01.

Figure 3 Presidential electoral margin and divided government on economic freedom index measures.

A brief review of anecdotal cases from Colombia and El Salvador also suggest that rightist leaders holding mandates tend to respond to voter preferences, downplaying doctrinaire neoliberal policies and promoting initiatives that have broader constituent support, including maintaining public order and security, and instituting targeted spending programs to help the poor (Reference Wiesehomeier, Doyle, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserWiesehomeier and Doyle 2014; Reference Koivumaeki, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserKoivumaeki 2014; Reference Meléndez, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserMeléndez 2014).Footnote 20

The experience of Colombian president Álvaro Uribe shows how a mandate affects policies under rightist rule. For more than forty years, Colombia has faced security issues and armed conflict with guerrillas, particularly with the Marxist-Leninist Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia (FARC). In 2002, Uribe presented himself as a political outsider who would address problems that the two long-standing political parties in Colombia, the Liberal Party and Conservative Party, could not seem to solve, namely, to root out and end armed conflict with the FARC (Reference Wills-Otero, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserWills-Otero 2014, 199). Security concerns took precedence in both of Uribe’s terms (2002–2006, 2006–2010). Indeed, the budget for the military and police force increased from 2 percent of GDP in 1990 to 6.35 percent in 2008 (Reference Wills-Otero, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserWills-Otero 2014, 206). A milder form of neoliberalism also emerged under Uribe. Although Uribe encouraged foreign direct investment and private ownership and negotiated free trade agreements, part and parcel of the neoliberal model, he recognized that not all Colombians favored market policies.Footnote 21 Uribe responded by backing government-financed social development policies in education, health, and public services as part of a strategy to encourage more equal income distribution. Uribe also instituted policies, such as Families in Action, providing state relief to the most vulnerable families. The assistance programs increased the total number of beneficiaries from 83,726 in 2001 to 1,559,369 in 2007 (Reference Wills-Otero, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserWills-Otero 2014, 206). Thus, Uribe enhanced security, promoted more equitable income distribution, and implemented more targeted spending programs for the poor, all apparently as measures for helping to achieve his electoral goals.

A similar situation occurred in El Salvador, where rightist leaders promoted security issues and implemented social policies to galvanize support from the masses. Prior to 2009, the rightwing Nationalist Republican Alliance (ARENA) Party had won every postwar presidential election and “dominated the legislative assembly, either itself or with its rightist allies” (Reference Koivumaeki, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserKoivumaeki 2014, 268). Part of ARENA’s success stemmed from selling itself as a capable defender of public security, an important concern as El Salvador had suffered a long and bloody civil war (1980–1992). Related to the wartime cleavage, ARENA attempted to link its main party rival, the Farabundo Martí National Liberation Front, with its violent past. ARENA’s success also arose from the government’s softening of its neoliberal image. Although over the decades, ARENA governments had implemented market-oriented policies, a backlash formed against neoliberalism, particularly in the early 2000s.Footnote 22 President Antonio Saca (2004–2009) responded to extensive criticism, much of it coming from poor voters, a key constituency of ARENA, by initiating Plan Oportunidades. Oportunidades offered conditional cash transfer and microcredits to the poorest Salvadorans. As of 2008, Oportunidades served seventy-seven municipalities, with the aim of lowering extreme poverty (Reference Koivumaeki, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserKoivumaeki 2014, 276, 287). ARENA cast its electoral fortunes not on adhering to the most orthodox form of neoliberalism but rather with highlighting its security competence and offering government programs for the poor.Footnote 23

A caveat is needed for the clarity of responsibility and political mandate theory developed here. The implication of the argument is not that rightist governments without mandates draw attention to neoliberal policies at the expense of security and social issues. Rightist governments of all stripes will support policies that give themselves the best chance of winning elections. The point here is that rightist governments holding mandates are more likely to downplay orthodox market reforms and highlight popular issues consistent with core conservative themes because voters can clearly assign responsibility under such institutional arrangements.

Conclusion

Although many works have investigated the variation in economic policies under leftist governments, policy differences among rightist governments in Latin America have received minimal attention. The different economic policies of rightist governments, which arguably should prefer the same policies based on their presumed ideological preferences, present a puzzle in the political economy literature.

Building on the political mandate and clarity of responsibility argument, this research helps to understand why rightist executives holding political mandates appear to go against their presumed preferences for the neoliberal model. We argued that because of the growing opposition to most orthodox market reforms, rightists holding mandates often downplay neoliberalism, particularly with regard to micro-level economic policies, and instead rely on public stances to maintain order and security, uphold conservative positions on social issues, and increase government programs for the poor to win elections and stay in office.

There are limitations to this study. First, the years available for the dependent variable hamper efforts to extend the analysis prior to 1995. Similarly, the relatively small sample of countries and years available for rightist governments in Latin America also limit empirical investigation. Despite the limitations, the work holds important implications on policy. First, the fact that relatively few empirical works investigate policies under rightist governments in Latin America provides an opportunity to make an initial step into understanding economic policies beyond leftist governments. Second, the research also builds on earlier studies in American and Latin American politics primarily outside of international political economy, showing the benefits of borrowing theories developed in other research areas to broaden our ideas about policies. Third, the research explains why some rightist governments support policies that seem to challenge their expected ideological preferences, helping to solve a puzzle in the literature.

The work presented here offers opportunities for further assessment of the mandate and clarity of responsibility theory. Previous work has investigated the effect of mandates on leftist governments in Latin America (Reference BiglaiserBiglaiser 2016). Future studies could investigate the effects of mandate and clarity of responsibility on left and right governments throughout the developing world. Is Latin America an exception? Are the factors that affect policies under left and right governments in Latin America relevant elsewhere? Additionally, it might be useful to test the theories not only in presidential systems but also in parliamentary governments. Do parliamentary governments with dominance by one party affect economic policies relative to narrowly won elections or where the winning parties need to form a coalition? Future empirical studies also could explore the trade-off between policies that support security and social conservative values, and maintaining hands-off government policies such as neoliberalism. The takeaway from the results is that clarity of responsibility produced by political mandates potentially gives voters more voice in economic policies.

Additional File

The additional file for this article can be found as follows:

Appendix

Table A1 Descriptive statistics.

Figure A1 Presidential margins and ideology scores for all rightist presidents.

Figure A2 Effects of unified government and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores (full model).

Acknowledgements

We acknowledge the helpful comments from the reviewers as well as from Jae-Jae Spoon and Amalia Pulido Gómez. We thank Brandon Stewart for his research assistance. We also thank seminar participants from the Universidad Católica de Chile and Universidad de la República in Uruguay. Portions of this research were supported by a 2013 Fulbright grant.

Footnotes

1 See, for example, Castañeda (Reference Castañeda2006), Levitsky and Roberts (Reference Levitsky, Roberts, Levitsky and Roberts2011), and Weyland, Madrid, and Hunter (Reference Weyland, Madrid and Hunter2010).

2 There are possible differences among rightist (and center-right) governments, as well as in some cases center governments, but for the sake of clarity, we refer to them all as rightist based on the self-identification of most as parties from the right, their lack of identification with leftist parties, as well as the use of several sources, discussed later in the article, which classify the parties as non-leftist.

3 Johnson and Crisp (Reference Johnson and Crisp2003) discuss mandate in the context of winning an election but without consideration of victory size or if the president and legislature come from the same party.

4 Rightist ideology differs from parties on the left, as leftists usually prefer increased government involvement in the economy (Reference Baker and GreeneBaker and Greene 2011; Reference Magaloni and RomeroMagaloni and Romero 2008; Reference StevensonStevenson 2001). Similarly, Johnson and Crisp (Reference Johnson and Crisp2003, 134) find that right-of-center legislatures are correlated with more market-oriented policies.

5 As presidents not winning by a landslide, and those who govern under divided government, hold less control over policy outcomes, they are less clearly responsible for said policies.

6 As Baker and Greene (Reference Baker and Greene2011, 44) report, “voters’ declining enthusiasm for market reforms” is an important reason for leftist victories in presidential elections.

7 See works by Gibson (Reference Gibson1996), Luna and Rovira Kaltwasser (Reference Luna and Rovira Kaltwasser2014), and Middlebrook (Reference Middlebrook2000), who investigate the politics of the right in Latin America.

8 See also Luna and Rovira Kaltwasser (Reference Luna and Rovira Kaltwasser2014, 4) and Eaton (Reference Eaton, Luna and Rovira Kaltwasser2014, 78), who discuss differences between the right and left on economic policy, with rightist parties preferring a free and unfettered market and minimal state intervention. In the context of the OECD, Boix (Reference Boix1998) similarly argues social democrats use the public sector to support economic growth and promote equality while conservatives employ the private provision of investment to address development.

9 See also Remmer (Reference Remmer2012, 953), who contends that a growing economy “creates opportunities for political leaders to offer voters programs of poverty reduction, improved social equity, economic nationalism, and increased government spending.”

10 Mahon (Reference Mahon2003, 58) similarly reports increased hostility to extreme market solutions. He attributes much of Latin America’s turn away from the “Washington Consensus” to adverse external trends (e.g., growing economic uncertainty, slowing credit flows, and the rise in protectionism by the North) and worsening social and economic problems (e.g., increases in crime, unemployment, and inequality).

11 As Baker (Reference Baker2003, 428; emphasis added) notes, in comparing trade with other economic reforms, “many citizens favorably single out free trade from the list of Latin America’s recent market reforms.”

12 See Campello (Reference Campello2014), who convincingly argues that left-leaning candidates have a high probability of betraying campaign promises and switching to neoliberal policies when elected during a currency crisis.

13 Although the financial community generally contributes more funds to the right, they also donate to the left in order to hedge their bets and gain access to elected officials.

14 Party orientation with respect to economic policy, coded based on the description of the party in the sources, using the following criteria: Right: for parties that are defined as conservative, Christian democratic, or right-wing; Left: for parties that are defined as communist, socialist, social democratic, or left-wing; Center: for parties that are defined as centrist or when party position can best be described as centrist.

15 See the Index of Economic Freedom website for more information about the methodology used for each freedom measure: http://www.heritage.org/index/book/methodology.

16 As Flores-Macías (Reference Flores-Macías2012, 26) notes, there are limitations with the index, as some indicators are fully or partially qualitative and depend on the judgment calls of experts. Despite the limitations, the index provides the most comprehensive measure for market openness.

17 Our theoretical argument is concerned with mandates producing greater clarity of responsibility (Reference Nadeau, Niemi and YoshinakaNadeau, Niemi, and Yoshinaka 2002; Reference Parker-StephenParker-Stephen 2013). We do not classify coalition governments as unified because the complexities of coalition governments make responsibility less clear to the electorate (Reference Hobolt, Tilley and BanducciHobolt, Tilley, and Banducci 2013). By excluding coalition governments from our measures of united governments, we provide the most conservative test of our theory.

18 We present a graph of ideology and presidential margins for all rightest presidents in Appendix Figure A1.

19 GDP growth also serves as a test of the retrospective voting approach, which claims that the electorate tends to punish governments during difficult economic times, while it is inclined to reward them in periods of economic growth.

20 Pledging conservative stances on social issues also is a common course followed by rightist leaders (e.g., Argentina, Chile, Ecuador, and Mexico; see Reference Eaton, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserEaton 2014, 83; Reference Morresi, Vommaro, Luna and Rovira KaltwasserMorresi and Vommaro 2014, 328) but, in the cases of Colombia and El Salvador, security concerns trumped social issues.

21 Table 1 also shows that in 2002, only 10.4 percent Colombians responded that they were very (or rather) satisfied with the functioning of the market economy in their country.

22 Table 1 also indicates El Salvador’s low level (22.7 percent) of satisfaction with the market in 2005.

23 The decision by Mexican President Ernesto Zedillo, a US-trained economist, to expropriate a few foreign firms between 1995 and 1998 (Reference HajzlerHajzler 2012), at the same time as growing unpopularity with neoliberal policies (e.g., a 1995 Latinobarómetro poll showed that more than 77 percent of the respondents believed that the country was in a bad or very bad economic situation and only 13 percent responded that they expected the situation to get better), and during mid-term elections, also is an example of clarity of responsibility and political mandate at work.

References

Baker, Andy. 2003. “Why Is Trade Reform So Popular in Latin America? A Consumption-Based Theory of Trade Policy Preferences.” World Politics 55(3): 423455. DOI: 10.1353/wp.2003.0014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Andy, and Greene, Kenneth F.. 2011. “The Latin American Left’s Mandate: Free-Market Policies and Issue Voting in New Democracies.” World Politics 63(1): 4377. DOI: 10.1017/S0043887110000286CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baltagi, Badi H., and Wu, Ping X.. 1999. “Unequally Spaced Panel Data Regressions with AR (1) Disturbances.” Econometric Theory 15(6): 814823. DOI: 10.1017/S0266466699156020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert J. 2013. “Democracy, Law and Order, and Economic Growth.” In 2013 Index of Economic Freedom, edited by Miller, Terry, Holmes, Kim R., and Feulner, Edwin J., 4158. Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation and Dow Jones & Company, Inc.Google Scholar
Beck, Thorsten, Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Levine, Ross. 2006. “Bank Supervision and Corruption in Lending.” Journal of Monetary Economics 53: 21312163. DOI: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.10.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, Thorsten, Clarke, George, Groff, Alberto, Keefer, Philip, and Walsh, Patrick. 2001. “New Tools and New Tests in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions.” World Bank Economic Review 15(1): 165176. DOI: 10.1093/wber/15.1.165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biglaiser, Glen. 2016. “Mandate and the Market: Policy Outcomes under the Left in Latin America.” Comparative Politics 48(2): 185204. DOI: 10.5129/001041516817037709CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biglaiser, Glen, and DeRouen, Karl. 2010. “The Effects of IMF Programs on U.S. Foreign Direct Investment in the Developing World.” Review of International Organizations 5(1): 7395. DOI: 10.1007/s11558-009-9071-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. 1998. Political Parties, Growth, and Equality: Conservative and Social Democratic Strategies in the World Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139174947CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campello, Daniela. 2014. “The Politics of Financial Booms and Crises: Evidence from Latin America.” Comparative Political Studies 47(2): 260286. DOI: 10.1177/0010414013488539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castañeda, Jorge G. 2006. “Latin America’s Left Turn.” Foreign Affairs 81(3): 2843. DOI: 10.2307/20031965CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conley, Patricia H. 2001. Presidential Mandates: How Elections Shape the National Agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
De la Torre, Augusto, Ize, Alain, and Schmukler, Sergio L.. 2011. Financial Development in Latin America and the Caribbean: The Road Ahead. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-8847-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, David. 2012. “Pressures to Privatize? The IMF, Globalization, and Partisanship in Latin America.” Political Research Quarterly 65(3): 572585. DOI: 10.1177/1065912911411100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dreher, Axel. 2006. “IMF and Economic Growth: The Effects of Programs, Loans, and Compliance with Conditionality.” World Development 34(5): 769788. DOI: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duch, Raymond M., and Stevenson, Randolph T.. 2008. The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511755934CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, Kent. 2014. “New Strategies of the Latin American Right: Beyond Parties and Elections.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 7593. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Flores-Macías, Gustavo A. 2010. “Statist vs. Pro-Market: Explaining Leftist Governments’ Economic Policies in Latin America.” Comparative Politics 42(4): 413433. DOI: 10.5129/001041510X12911363510033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flores-Macías, Gustavo A. 2012. After Neoliberalism: The Left and Economic Reforms in Latin America. New York: Oxford University Press. DOI: 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199891658.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1991. Debt, Development, and Democracy: Modern Political Economy in Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gibson, Edward L. 1996. Class and Conservative Parties: Argentina in Comparative Perspective. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Grossback, Lawrence J., Peterson, David A. M., and Stimson, James A.. 2007. “Electoral Mandates in American Politics.” British Journal of Political Science 37: 711730. DOI: 10.1017/S0007123407000385CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hajzler, Christopher 2012. “Expropriation of Foreign Direct Investment: Sectoral Patterns from 1993 to 2006.” Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 148(1): 119149. DOI: 10.1007/s10290-011-0103-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heritage Foundation. 2017. “Index of Economic Freedom.” http://www.heritage.org/index/.Google Scholar
Hidalgo, Manuel, 2009. “Hugo Chávez’s Petro-Socialism.” Journal of Democracy 20(2): 7892. DOI: 10.1353/jod.0.0073CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobolt, Sara, Tilley, James, and Banducci, Susan. 2013. “Clarity of Responsibility: How Government Cohesion Conditions Performance Voting.” European Journal of Political Research 52(2): 164187. DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.2012.02072.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D.. 2012. Democracy and the Left: Social Policy and Inequality in Latin America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. DOI: 10.7208/chicago/9780226356556.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, Nathan M. 2003. “Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment.” International Organization 57: 587616. DOI: 10.1017/S0020818303573040CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Gregg B., and Crisp, Brian F.. 2003. “Mandates, Powers, and Policies.” American Journal of Political Science 47(1): 128142. DOI: 10.1111/1540-5907.00009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Gregg B., and Ryu, Sooh-Rhee. 2010. “Repudiating or Rewarding Neoliberalism? How Broken Campaign Promises Condition Economic Voting in Latin America.” Latin American Politics and Society 52(4): 124. DOI: 10.1111/j.1548-2456.2010.00096.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Charles O. 1999. Separate but Equal Branches: Congress and the Presidency. 2nd ed. New York: Chatham House.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Stephen B. 2013. Globalization and Austerity Politics in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Robert R. 2011. “The Political Left, the Export Boom, and the Populist Temptation.” In The Resurgence of the Latin American Left, edited by Levitsky, Steven and Roberts, Kenneth M., 93116. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Koivumaeki, Riitta-Ilona. 2014. “El Salvador: Societal Cleavages, Strategic Elites, and the Success of the Right.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 268293. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Lee, Hoon, Biglaiser, Glen, and Staats, Joseph L.. 2014. “The Effects of Political Risk on Different Entry Modes of Foreign Direct Investment.” International Interactions 40: 683710. DOI: 10.1080/03050629.2014.899225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Roberts, Kenneth M.. 2011. “Introduction: Latin America’s ‘Left Turn’: A Framework for Analysis.” In The Resurgence of the Latin American Left, edited by Levitsky, Steven and Roberts, Kenneth M., 128. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Light, Paul. 1989. The President’s Agenda: Domestic Policy Choice from Kennedy to Clinton. 3rd ed. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Luna, Juan Pablo, and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, eds. 2014. The Resilience of the Latin American Right. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Madrid, Raúl L. 2010. “The Origins of the Two Lefts in Latin America.” Political Science Quarterly 125(4): 587610. DOI: 10.1002/j.1538-165X.2010.tb00686.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz, and Romero, Vidal. 2008. “Partisan Cleavages, State Retrenchment, and Free Trade: Latin America in the 1990s.” Latin American Research Review 43(2): 107135. DOI: 10.1353/lar.0.0005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahon, James E. Jr. 1996. Mobile Capital and Latin American Development. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Mahon, James E. Jr. 2003. “Good-Bye to the Washington Consensus.” Current History 102(661): 5864.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott. 2006. “The Crisis of Representation in the Andes.” Journal of Democracy 17(3): 1327. DOI: 10.1353/jod.2006.0048CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mainwaring, Scott, and Shugart, Matthew Soberg, eds. 1997. Presidentialism and Democracy in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9781139174800CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meléndez, Carlos. 2014. “Is There a Right Track in Post-Party System Collapse Scenarios? Comparing the Andean Countries.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 167193. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Middlebrook, Kevin, ed. 2000. Conservative Parties, the Right, and Democracy in Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Morresi, Sergio, and Vommaro, Gabriel. 2014. “Argentina: The Difficulties of the Partisan Right and the Case of Propuesta Republicana.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 319346. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Mosley, Layna. 2003. Global Capital and National Governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511615672Google Scholar
Murillo, M. Victoria. 2000. “From Populism to Neoliberalism: Labor Unions and Market Reforms in Latin America.” World Politics 52(2): 135168. DOI: 10.1017/S0043887100002586CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murillo, M. Victoria. 2009. Political Competition, Partisanship, and Policymaking in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nadeau, Richard, Niemi, Richard G., and Yoshinaka, Antoine. 2002. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context across Time and Nations.” Electoral Studies 21(3): 403423. DOI: 10.1016/S0261-3794(01)00002-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parker-Stephen, Evan. 2013. “Clarity of Responsibility and Economic Evaluations.” Electoral Studies 32(3): 506511. DOI: 10.1016/j.electstud.2013.05.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pop-Eleches, Grigore. 2009. From Economic Crisis to Reform: IMF Programs in Latin America and Eastern Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham Jr, and Whitten, Guy D.. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37(2): 391414. DOI: 10.2307/2111378CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pedersen, Mogens N. 1979. “The Dynamics of European Party Systems: Changing Patterns of Electoral Volatility.” European Journal of Political Research 7(1): 126. DOI: 10.1111/j.1475-6765.1979.tb01267.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Remmer, Karen L. 1998. “The Politics of Neoliberal Economic Reform in South America.” Studies in Comparative International Development 33(2): 329. DOI: 10.1007/BF02687406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Remmer, Karen L. 2012. “The Rise of Leftist-Populist Governance in Latin America: The Roots of Electoral Change.” Comparative Political Studies 45(8): 947972. DOI: 10.1177/0010414011428595CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Kenneth M. 2012. “Market Reform, Programmatic (De)alignment, and Party System Stability in Latin America.” Comparative Political Studies 46(11): 709732.Google Scholar
Roberts, Kenneth M. 2014. “Democracy, Free Markets, and the Rightist Dilemma in Latin America.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 2547. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Roberts, Kenneth M., and Arce, Moises. 1998. “Neoliberalism and Lower-Class Voting Behavior in Latin America.” Comparative Political Studies 31(2): 217246. DOI: 10.1177/0010414098031002004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stevenson, Randolph T. 2001. “The Economy and Policy Mood: A Fundamental Dynamic of Democratic Politics?American Journal of Political Science 45(3): 620–33. DOI: 10.2307/2669242CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2002. Globalization and Its Discontents. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 2001. Mandates and Democracy: Neoliberalism by Surprise in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511612978CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vreeland, James Raymond. 2003. The IMF and Economic Development. Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511615726CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weinbaum, Marvin G., and Judd, Dennis R.. 1970. “In Search of the Mandated Congress.” Midwest Journal of Political Science 14: 276302. DOI: 10.2307/2110196CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weyland, Kurt. 2009. “The Rise of Latin America’s Two Lefts: Insights from the Rentier State Theory.” Comparative Politics 41(2): 145164. DOI: 10.5129/001041509X12911362971918CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weyland, Kurt, Madrid, Raúl L., and Hunter, Wendy, eds. 2010. Leftist Governments in Latin America: Successes and Shortcomings. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. DOI: 10.1017/CBO9780511778742CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wibbels, Erik. 2006. “Dependency Revisited: International Markets, Business Cycles, and Social Spending in the Developing World.” International Organization 60(2): 433468. DOI: 10.1017/S0020818306060139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wibbels, Erik, and Arce, Moisés. 2003. “Globalization, Taxation, and Burden-Shifting in Latin America.” International Organization 57(1): 111136. DOI: 10.1017/S0020818303571041CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiesehomeier, Nina, and Benoit, Kenneth. 2009. “Presidents, Parties, and Policy Competition.” Journal of Politics 71(4): 14351447. DOI: 10.1017/S0022381609990193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiesehomeier, Nina, and Doyle, David. 2014. “Profiling the Electorate: Ideology and Attitudes of Rightwing Voters.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 4874. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Wills-Otero, Laura. 2014. “Colombia: Analyzing the Strategies for Political Action of Álvaro Uribe’s Government, 2002–2010.” In The Resilience of the Latin American Right, edited by Luna, Juan Pablo and Rovira Kaltwasser, Cristóbal, 194218. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2015. World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Percent saying they are very (or rather) satisfied with the functioning of the market economy in the country.

Figure 1

Table 2 Percent agreeing or strongly agreeing with the statement: The privatization of state companies has been beneficial to the country.

Figure 2

Table 3 Political mandate and market reforms in Latin America.

Figure 3

Figure 1 Effects of unified government and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores.

Figure 4

Figure 2 Effects of right party ideology and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores.

Figure 5

Table 4 Political mandate and market reforms in Latin America for right parties.

Figure 6

Figure 3 Presidential electoral margin and divided government on economic freedom index measures.

Figure 7

Table A1 Descriptive statistics.

Figure 8

Figure A1 Presidential margins and ideology scores for all rightist presidents.

Figure 9

Figure A2 Effects of unified government and presidential vote share on expected economic freedom scores (full model).

Supplementary material: PDF

Biglaiser and McGauvran supplementary material

Biglaiser and McGauvran supplementary material
Download Biglaiser and McGauvran supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 34.1 KB