The tide is turning. Ferment is in the air. Reform or even transformation of foreign direct investment governance appears on the way.Footnote 1 Different proposals are advanced, different proposals trashed. Some defend the current arbitral system of investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS). Others support the alternative of a multilateral investment court system. Some focus on market mechanisms. Others on national sovereignty. What we lack is a framework for comparatively assessing the range of institutional alternatives in light of their relative trade-offs.Footnote 2 This Article provides such a framework. Our central claim is that all institutional alternatives are highly imperfect because of the dynamics of participation within them, and thus criticism of one institutional alternative without comparatively assessing the imperfections of real-life alternatives is of little help and can make for bad public policy.
To assess trade-offs, one should address two issues in parallel: goal choice and institutional choice. Scholars commonly start by specifying the goals of international law.Footnote 3 Law-and-economics scholars focus on efficiency.Footnote 4 Rawlsian-oriented scholars focus on fairness.Footnote 5 And realist-oriented ones focus on interstate relations, power, and conflict.Footnote 6 For international investment law, commentators conventionally describe these goals as fairness, resource allocation efficiency, and peace. They stress the goals in different ways, but they have all been fundamental in contests over the construction of the international investment law regime and its institutions over time.Footnote 7 We recast these three goals in light of the broader principle of accountability under the rule of law, which underpins (or, we argue, should underpin) these goals.
Inevitably, observers will disagree over how to specify goals and theorize justice. We argue that, whatever one's preferred goal, different institutional processes will mediate the pursuit of that goal in highly imperfect ways. All institutional processes are imperfect, and all of them are imperfect in different ways given the dynamics of participation within them. These dynamics result in different minoritarian and majoritarian biases. Institutional choice is thus required, and to make such choices, one needs to compare institutional processes.
After applying the comparative institutional analytic framework to a range of market, political, and judicial options for resolving investment disputes, we conclude with two recommendations. First, policymakers and scholars should pay greater heed to the place of institutional complementarity in support of the rule of law in domestic jurisdictions as a central consideration of the international investment regime. The argument for complementarity is that, where possible, international processes should be structured not as substitutes but as complements to domestic processes to assure government accountability. Second, policymakers and scholars should recognize that countries face a range of contexts—in terms of capital endowment, market size, ideology, institutional development, and historical legacy—and that these contexts will affect their institutional choice.
The Article proceeds in five parts. Part I briefly presents the historical backdrop of investment regulation and dispute settlement, from its early roots to the setting of contemporary debates over institutional reform. Part II examines three conventional normative goals for investment protection: fairness, efficiency, and peace. It then frames them in light of the overarching principle of accountability under the rule of law. Part III presents the comparative institutional analytic framework with its focus on the dynamics of participation in institutional processes so that trade-offs among institutional choices are assessed. Part IV applies the framework to evaluate different market, political, and judicial alternatives for handling international investment disputes. Part V concludes regarding the choice of options available given the different contexts states face.
I. A New Debate in Investment Law
A. Emergence and Evolution of ISDS
Conflict over governmental treatment of property held by foreign nationals has existed for centuries, but it intensified in the seventeenth century with the rise of states and imperial, mercantilist competition among them.Footnote 8 To resolve conflicts, states turned to some of the methods still used today, such as negotiation and mediation, as well as others that are no longer permissible, such as armed intervention and the hiring of privateers to collect debts.Footnote 9
States submitted foreign investment conflicts to international adjudication as early as 1794, when mixed arbitral commissions under the Jay Treaty addressed the settlement of debts to British creditors.Footnote 10 Over time, multiple commissions and ad hoc tribunals were formed. They developed international investment law in the shadow of state power and coercion, finding the law's sources in customary international law and general principles of law.Footnote 11
After World War II, industrialized countries tried to formalize their views of investment law in treaties.Footnote 12 The United States, for example, promoted treaties of Friendship, Commerce, and Navigation (FCN treaties) with its allies.Footnote 13 Under some FCN treaties, states could invoke interstate dispute settlement (including before the International Court of Justice (ICJ)) by offering diplomatic protection after their nationals had exhausted local remedies.Footnote 14
During the Post-War years, the United States and Western European countries increasingly called for multilateral initiatives that would protect their and their nationals’ property in newly decolonized territories.Footnote 15 Developing countries resisted these attempts by pioneering a countervailing effort to create a New International Economic Order that recognized their sovereign ownership of their natural resources and championed the exclusive use of domestic law and institutions.Footnote 16 As a result of this clash of perspectives, multilateral treaty-making initiatives addressing substantive rights owed to foreign investors—then a highly contested matter—went nowhere.Footnote 17 However, the negotiation of the Convention on the Settlement of Investment Disputes Between States and Nationals of Other States proceeded, which created a mechanism for the use of ad hoc tribunals to enforce investment commitments that might be separately made through domestic law, contract, or treaty.Footnote 18 This convention created the International Centre for Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID)—an international organization that is part of the World Bank Group.Footnote 19
ICSID had a slow start, administering mostly contractual disputes between foreign investors and states.Footnote 20 A more favorable climate toward foreign direct investment developed, abetted by the fall of the Berlin Wall, the collapse of the Soviet Union, and the rise of the “Washington Consensus” for development policy.Footnote 21 This conjunction catalyzed the negotiation of scores of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) containing ISDS, followed by increased litigation under them.Footnote 22 Through these BITs, investors could bring claims without the need for home state espousal or (in most cases) the exhaustion of local remedies. Developing countries signed these treaties in the hope of attracting investment and to reduce outside political interference,Footnote 23 but often with limited information regarding their implications.Footnote 24
A dramatic rise in ISDS cases based on BITs generated a backlash against ISDS, which intensified following the 2007 global financial crisis and the filing of politically charged cases implicating developed countries’ public policies.Footnote 25 The total number of ISDS cases is unknown because arbitrations may be kept confidential, but the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) reports that as of July 31, 2017, there have been 817 publicly known ISDS cases, with 77 of them being filed in 2015 alone.Footnote 26 Investors from Europe and North America have largely brought these claims, which have involved at least 114 countries as respondents.Footnote 27 Many scholars and NGOs contended that ISDS developed from coercive origins, reflects asymmetric power differentials, and, as a result, is unfair, imbalanced, and illegitimate.Footnote 28 Although other scholars contested these depictions,Footnote 29 the media often adopted this frame, emphasizing ISDS's undemocratic and highly clandestine nature.Footnote 30
Governments responded to these criticisms and the risk of significant liability from large ISDS awards. In the last decade, countries have terminated BITs with ISDS clauses (such as Ecuador, Indonesia, and South Africa), withdrew from the ICSID Convention (notably, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Venezuela), threatened to leave it (including Argentina, El Salvador, and Nicaragua), or created new constraints on using ISDS (such as Norway and New Zealand).Footnote 31 In response to this backlash, multiple reform proposals gradually emerged and many states created new model BITs (e.g., Canada and the United States) or approaches (e.g., the European Union).Footnote 32
B. Challenges to the Current ISDS Model
For many commentators, the main problem with the current system of international investment law enforcement is that it is based on a model of international commercial arbitration. It relies on ad hoc tribunals of party-appointed arbitrators to resolve one-off disputes, even though the disputes may involve public law and policy.Footnote 33 The tribunals interpret vague treaty rules—such as provisions demanding “fair and equitable treatment” and prohibitions against “measures tantamount to expropriation.” The system lacks an appeal process, other than a narrow annulment proceeding that has been routinely criticized.Footnote 34 Conflicting decisions, sometimes involving the same facts, raise rule-of-law and coherence concerns.Footnote 35 Because the arbitrators are appointed on an ad hoc basis as opposed to a fixed term and are allowed to represent clients in other arbitrations (conduct known as “double hatting”), they face incentives to decide cases in a manner that favors the party that appointed them and to assure a flow of future cases, sparking challenges to their independence and impartiality.Footnote 36 Collectively, these individuals constitute a small club of self-regulated decision-makers that lacks gender and geographic diversity.Footnote 37 Given the potential for large damage awards, the threat of litigation, it is contended, can chill regulation.Footnote 38
In response to these critiques, states and commentators have proposed a range of institutional reforms that are being discussed in a working group of the United Nations Conference on International Trade Law (UNCITRAL).Footnote 39 Prominently, the European Union (EU) has promoted a multilateral investment court system where private investors retain standing to file claims directly against states. At its core, this “systemic” change would create a tribunal of first instance and an appellate body, with the judges having fixed terms, paid a regular salary, and selected on a random basis from a roster designated by states.Footnote 40 These judges accordingly would be restricted from acting as counsel in other cases. The European Union has already concluded agreements containing such a system—designed for bilateral relations, but including flexibilities for multilateralization—with Canada, Singapore, Vietnam, and Mexico, and indications that more agreements with these features will follow.Footnote 41 As one of the world's largest senders and receivers of foreign direct investment and given that around half of all existing BITs involve EU members, the European Union exercises considerable leverage in this reform process.Footnote 42
In contrast, Brazil and South Africa have proposed alternatives involving mediation, possibly backed by state-to-state adjudication in which the state decides whether to espouse an investor's claims.Footnote 43 In parallel, India adopted a new model BIT that, while it incorporates ISDS, conditions its use on the initial pursuit of remedies before domestic courts for at least five years.Footnote 44 India and China also have signaled interest in an appellate process, similar to that included in the EU's proposal.Footnote 45 While the United States previously defended ISDS, in October 2017, Robert Lighthizer, the United States Trade Representative (USTR), signaled a potential shift in the U.S. position regarding ISDS, suggesting that investors should rely on market mechanisms, such as political risk insurance.Footnote 46 In this context, the ICSID Secretariat also has advanced consideration of an incremental updating of the ICSID Regulations and Rules.Footnote 47
Much of the debate in the United States and Europe has focused on assessing whether the European Union's proposed multilateral investment court system constitutes an improvement or even a significant change.Footnote 48 The European Union's reform proposal and ISDS, however, are just two alternative adjudicatory forms. Other adjudicatory and non-adjudicatory options exist, including market-oriented mechanisms such as insurance and contract. Thus, the broader question arises: What are the relative trade-offs among different market, political, and judicial institutional alternatives for addressing investment disputes?
II. Normative Goals of Investment Law
To assess institutional options comparatively, we first examine three goals that have been advanced to justify the current ISDS model: fairness, resource allocation efficiency, and peace. We reconstruct these goals to place them in their best light in terms of justification and fit from a perspective of reflective equilibrium.Footnote 49 As an increasing number of countries are both senders and receivers of foreign direct investment, a greater number operate under a veil of ignorance as to whether they could be claimants or respondents in investment disputes. This trend is conducive to an approach that is more balanced in terms of the characterization of investment law goals, which we argue has developed over the past decade. We address these goals in three subsections in which we build our argument from policymaker statements and ISDS jurisprudence as they have developed, and (in doing so) we explain why a one-sided view of fairness, efficiency, and peace from the perspectives of the investor and investment promotion is flawed (although supported in early ISDS jurisprudence and policymaker statements). We then reframe these goals in terms of a single, overarching, umbrella principle that we contend encompasses them analytically and is conducive to their achievement consequentially—accountability under the rule of law.
A. Fairness
A first commonly expressed goal of the ISDS system, as advocated by its defenders, is fairness.Footnote 50 ISDS, it is contended, provides access to justice for aggrieved investors claiming unfair treatment.Footnote 51 From this perspective, ISDS provides a readily available, neutral, adjudicatory alternative for investors who are unable to obtain justice before national institutions that are politically subservient or biased.Footnote 52 The creation of the ISDS system through ICSID supported this aim. ICSID stressed the goal of fairness as a “paramount objective” through which it can make a “real contribution … in restoring the climate of mutual confidence between states and investors.”Footnote 53
It is commonly argued, in stylized fashion, that the investor faces what law-and-economics scholars refer to as a time inconsistency or “hold-up” problem. In essence, the investor may have bargaining power when it makes the investment, but that bargaining power diminishes after it invests capital that it cannot easily and quickly withdraw when conditions deteriorate.Footnote 54 As ISDS arbitrator and scholar Michael Reisman writes,
A common feature of foreign direct investment is that the investor has sunk substantial capital in the host State … [such that] parity will cease and things will tilt heavily in favor of the respondent State. Unless, that is, both sides appreciate that if negotiations fail, compulsory arbitration will follow.Footnote 55
Many tribunals, especially earlier in their development of ISDS jurisprudence, focused on fairness toward foreign investors. In this vein, the tribunal in the case Pope & Talbot v. Canada stated that “[t]he aim of [the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)] seems to be… to present to investors the kind of hospitable climate that would insulate them from political risks or incidents of unfair treatment.”Footnote 56 In the words of the Corn Products v. Mexico tribunal (with former ICJ Judge Greenwood presiding), the focus of ISDS is on the “investor … seeking to enforce what it asserts are its own rights under the treaty.”Footnote 57
However, since around the mid-2000s, ISDS decisions increasingly recognize that fairness should not be viewed in one-sided terms focusing only on the foreign investor, given that the state has a responsibility to balance other welfare goals with the protection of investment.Footnote 58 Tribunals’ development of the principle of a state's “right to regulate” in light of social welfare goals reflects a broader concern of fairness toward other stakeholders.Footnote 59 Tribunals thus generally “balance” investor rights and other claims affecting social welfare.Footnote 60 When they do so, they implicitly recognize that representative governments should take into account the interests of other stakeholders as well when they make decisions that can affect investors. This development is captured in some contemporary BITs,Footnote 61 including the preamble of the Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA), which references the protection of “investments and investors” with “the right of the Parties to regulate in the public interest,” and the 2012 U.S. model BIT, which includes the “objective[]” of consistency “with the protection of health, safety, and the environment, and the promotion of internationally recognized labor rights.”Footnote 62
Given the lack of an appellate mechanism in ISDS and the contentiousness of commentary, debates continue regarding the conceptualization of fairness. Many contend—and we agree—that limiting the concept of fairness to apply only to foreign investors is itself unbalanced and asymmetric, and thus unfair.Footnote 63 Such asymmetry has raised questions regarding the evenhandedness of ISDS, and thus of the international rule of law. Some contend that BITs should be revised to create explicit obligations for investors and the right to sue investors for breaching those obligations; indeed, some new BITs include obligations on investors.Footnote 64 Yet even if BITs are not so revised, broader interests are still encompassed within the state's right to regulate and balance social welfare goals.
In our view, focusing on fairness only with regard to foreign investors builds from a number of flawed assumptions and can create a structural tilt against state regulation and the interests of other stakeholders represented by the state. First, a one-sided focus is based on assumptions that can overstate the relative position of the state in relation to investors, which are often large powerful corporations from comparatively rich nations that have many options to protect themselves. Rather than being simply law-abiding, risk-taking victims of excessive, opportunistic governments, investors may have “unclean hands” and their actions can damage the environment, contribute to the violation of human rights, and raise other social concerns.
Second, a one-sided focus on fairness obscures the fact that foreign investors may be in a much stronger position than other stakeholders in relation to the host state through their ability to lobby, bargain contractually, obtain insurance, and harness home state diplomacy. In practice, foreign investors may procure investments under less than transparent conditions to the prejudice of other stakeholders within the state. While it is possible that some governments have the institutional capacity to perform a proper balancing of stakeholder interests, the threat of using ISDS can further advantage well-resourced foreign investors, creating a structural tilt against state regulation that is responsive to the concerns of affected citizens.
Third, a one-sided view presumes domestic courts cannot be trusted. Yet, if this is the case, then domestic stakeholders can be prejudiced as well, but they have no access to a specialized forum to sue foreign investors. An asymmetric focus on fairness in the definition and interpretation of foreign investment law constrains host governments’ ability to hold powerful, corporate actors accountable in situations where the alternative of relying on citizen suits before domestic courts is limited or non-existent. Moreover, a traditional ISDS model of substitution could inhibit the development of independent, national adjudicatory processes to fairly assess and balance the different interests at stake.Footnote 65
B. Efficiency
A second goal of ISDS is to promote resource allocation efficiency through reducing the state's cost of capital and thus increasing national welfare and supporting economic development. The World Bank stressed this goal in creating ICSID and supporting the ensuing ISDS system. In the words of one of the delegates participating in the negotiation of the ICSID Convention: “economic development could not be achieved without capital and … developing countries would not obtain capital unless they provided adequate [legal] guarantees.”Footnote 66 Law-and-economics scholars highlight this goal. As Alan Sykes writes, “A credible promise of monetary compensation to investors, by contrast, in an amount set by neutral arbitrators, goes much further to reduce investment risk and to achieve the developing countries’ goal of lowering the foreign cost of capital.”Footnote 67
For a rational foreign investor, its choice to invest is a function of the margin of profit needed in light of the risk of investing. The investor's decision is a question of opportunity costs; the greater the risk, the more profit it will require if it is to invest in a location. The cost of capital for investors implicates a state's cost of capital directly and indirectly. States depend on investment, whether public or private, and whether foreign or domestic. Capital inflows into states can take different forms—through loans, bonds, and foreign direct investment. Directly, higher investment risk increases the state's borrowing costs because lenders and bond holders demand higher interest rates. Indirectly, higher risk premiums for foreign investors correlate with higher borrowing costs for states.Footnote 68 Overall, the risks associated with investing in a state affect the state's cost of capital for investment and thus resource allocation efficiency.
From the perspective of efficiency, the titles and preambles of many BITs reflect the goal of efficiency in terms of promoting private investment.Footnote 69 Accordingly, some investment tribunals have focused on investment promotion in interpreting BIT provisions.Footnote 70 In doing so, they can develop jurisprudential standards that appear to create a bias against any new regulation that may prejudice an investor. The tribunal in Tecmed v. Mexico, for example, maintained that the investor must “know beforehand any and all rules and regulation that will govern its investments, as well as the goals of the relevant policies and administrative practices or directives.”Footnote 71 This controversial and expansive phrasing of the standard suggests that regulation should be frozen and not developed in light of experience and democratic choice.
Yet, the dominant trend of investment tribunals is to balance investor protection with a state's right to regulate when deciding on investment claims, such as claims regarding alleged unfair treatment or indirect expropriation. This approach implicitly conceptualizes resource allocation efficiency from a broader social welfare perspective.Footnote 72 That is, from a law-and-economics perspective, resource allocation efficiency involves the optimality of investment protection, and not investment promotion per se. Otherwise, ISDS will have an anti-regulatory bent since the best way to attract investment would be to limit government regulation. Absolute investment protection is not optimal, and thus not efficient, because it precludes the balancing of other social welfare goals. Indeed, Anthea Roberts rightly points out that jurisprudence that focuses solely on investor protection could trigger state exit from the investment regime, “undermining investor protection and the promotion of efficient investments in the long term.”Footnote 73
Whether ISDS actually catalyzes investment is forcefully debated, as is the broader question whether increased foreign investment is even desirable as a development strategy.Footnote 74 As Robert Howse writes, the argument that BITs support development through incentivizing foreign investment is based on three premises: (1) that additional investment boosts economic growth and development; (2) that treaty protection will incentivize additional investment; and (3) that treaty protection is cost-effective compared to other state incentives for foreign investment.Footnote 75 All of these premises are contested, both empirically and in terms of economic theory.Footnote 76
The goal of resource allocation efficiency is an important one affecting aggregate national welfare and the prospects of economic growth and development. Yet, from a law-and-economics perspective, the goal of resource allocation efficiency should be framed in terms of optimal investment to advance social welfare, not investment protection per se.
C. Peace
A third normative goal of investment dispute settlement is to reduce interstate conflict and thus support peaceful and cooperative international relations.Footnote 77 From this perspective, the adjudication of disputes involving foreign investors helps ensure that investment disputes are resolved by law instead of force or other forms of coercion. Otherwise, investment disputes could trigger costly diplomatic confrontations between the host state and the investor's home state that could escalate and possibly undermine cooperation in other areas.
This goal was central to the World Bank's promotion of the ICSID regime. Ibrahim Shihata stressed the goal—perhaps opportunistically—at a time when the volume of foreign direct investment in developing countries was declining as a consequence of debt crises.Footnote 78 According to Shihata, ISDS was superior because it effectively encourages investment “without inviting the abuses of diplomatic protection” of the past.Footnote 79 This framing particularly resonated among Latin American countries that had suffered reprisals by the United States and European powers in the form of “gunboat diplomacy”Footnote 80 to protect their nationals—actions that generated resistance among Latin American nations to join a system for the international adjudication of investment disputes.Footnote 81
Because the home states of investors historically used coercive methods to resolve investment disputes, some scholars defend ISDS by recalling the past. For example, Judge Schwebel stresses that “the displacement of gunboat diplomacy by international arbitration is a very real achievement.”Footnote 82 Professor Andreas Lowenfeld, a U.S. negotiator of the ICSID Convention, writes in a NAFTA case that “the essential feature of investor-state arbitration, as it has developed since the ICSID Convention of 1965, … is that controversies between foreign investors and host states are insulated from political and diplomatic relations between states.”Footnote 83
This goal has a long pedigree and links with what is arguably the foremost goal of public international law: to ensure international peace.Footnote 84 Assessing whether this historical depiction overstates the past use of coercive methods or, rather, understates the coercive methods used today, is beyond this Article's scope. We nonetheless note that self-help through the use of force to recover debts is now prohibited under international law, so that arguments regarding the goal of peace arise in a very different context.Footnote 85 In part because of this change, many question the continued usefulness of discussing “depoliticization” in the contemporary context. Martins Paparinskis, for example, contends that it has weak empirical foundations and “has no self-evident use for conceptualizing and resolving modern challenges.”Footnote 86 Even with ISDS, he argues, the dispute remains just as politically sensitive.Footnote 87
We add to the debate that the conventional conception of ISDS in terms of depoliticization, once more, has had a rather one-sided, pro-investor focus—it promotes ISDS to advance this end. We contend that the goal of international cooperation between states is indeed an important one, but that it should be viewed equally in terms of reducing constraints on states’ ability to adapt regulation to changing contexts in light of experience and new information, including in relation to global and transnational initiatives—think, for example, of the policies behind the “tobacco carve-out” from using ISDS under the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement.Footnote 88
Accordingly, we focus on the relative impact of institutional design on the furtherance of the goal of international cooperation and peace. Although international disputes can become politicized under any system, the level of politicization can vary in light of institutional design. In international trade law, for example, the U.S. administration currently threatens to undermine the dispute settlement system of the World Trade Organization (WTO) by blocking the appointment of members to the WTO Appellate Body.Footnote 89 Commentators worry about the long-term consequences for trade relations if this dispute settlement system erodes. For the investment law world, this development raises concern if ISDS were replaced by a court built on the WTO Appellate Body model. The goals of cooperative and peaceful interstate relations, in other words, continue to raise issues of institutional choice.
D. Reframing the Goals: Protection of the Rule of Law
We contend that the three conventional goals of investment protection reflected in ISDS—fairness, efficiency, and peace—are linked both analytically and consequentially to a broader principle—accountability under the rule of law. In the words of ICJ Judge James Crawford, one of the main roles “of international law is to reinforce, and on occasions to institute, the rule of law internally.”Footnote 90 In our view, the rule of law provides the guiding principle for international investment law. The concept resonates with traditional justifications for investment law, such as the obligation not to “deny justice,”Footnote 91 contemporary arbitral jurisprudence regarding the “minimum standard of treatment” and “fair and equitable treatment,”Footnote 92 and the preamble and other provisions of treaties such as CETA and those based on the 2012 U.S. model BIT.Footnote 93
The meaning of the “rule of law” is, however, contested.Footnote 94 Many legal philosophers focus on abstract formal conceptions of the rule of law, such as the law's generality, equality of application, and certainty. Lon Fuller notably advanced eight elements that constitute conditions for the rule of law—law should be “general, publicized, prospective, clear, non-contradictory, compliable, consistently applied, and reasonably stable.”Footnote 95 Joseph Raz specified similar principles and divided them into two groups, the first focused on formal standards that provide certainty and predictability to guide action, and the second focused on legal machinery to make the first effective.Footnote 96 These formal concepts of the rule of law highlight the coordinative function of norms by providing a framework against which individuals and organizations might orient action, interact, and plan.Footnote 97
The rule of law becomes more contested when it includes substantive norms and goals, representing political choices, such as a democratic form of government, participation, deliberation, and individual rights. Leading philosophers and social theorists, such as Ronald Dworkin, Jeremy Waldron, Jurgen Habermas, and Philip Selznick, advance different substantive conceptions to attend to broader values realized through law.Footnote 98 In different ways, United Nations reports on the rule of law incorporate substantive conceptions,Footnote 99 as do reports of the Bretton Woods institutions supporting market-oriented development policies.Footnote 100
The rule of law, in our view, is best conceptualized from a socio-legal perspective that focuses on goals and practices. The goal of the rule of law is to create restraints on government in order to provide security and predictability so that individuals and firms can plan their pursuits and do so without fear.Footnote 101 Its basic conception is opposition to the arbitrary exercise of power. Ultimately, for the rule of law to become effective, it must be institutionalized as part of a culture of appropriate conduct.Footnote 102 From a socio-legal perspective, the rule of law provides restraints on arbitrary state behavior, backed by norms that enable people to reasonably know what is required of them, combined with the institutionalization of these norms so that they “count as a source of restraint and a normative resource” that may be used in practice.Footnote 103 Applied to investment law, the rule of law provides foreign investors with the security and predictability that state commitments to them will be upheld. It creates, in the words of investment tribunals, “legitimate expectations” on the part of investors, subject to the state's “right to regulate” to advance social welfare.Footnote 104 To the extent one views the rule of law as also involving processes of participation and deliberation of the governed regarding the institutions that govern them, then that conception has implications for investment dispute settlement as well, highlighting the role of domestic institutions that are closer to the governed, with international mechanisms serving as complements to them, as addressed below.Footnote 105
We contend that the socio-legal framing of the rule of law is linked with our conceptualization of the three goals of investment law discussed above both analytically and conceptually.Footnote 106 First, the rule of law principle can be viewed analytically as incorporating the concept of procedural fairness in terms of law's inner morality (in Fuller's sense when viewed in terms of actual practice).Footnote 107 John Rawls, for example, defines the rule of law as “the regular, impartial, and in this sense fair, administration of law.”Footnote 108 Notably, the concept of fairness under the rule of law is symmetric for all stakeholders, and thus does not privilege foreign investors; for other stakeholders in the investment process, for example, the rule of law helps ensure that government officials do not engage in corrupt transactions or otherwise favor foreign investors over other interests.Footnote 109 Viewed consequentially, there is good reason to believe that the rule of law contributes to fairness, as the Marxist historian E.P. Thompson stressed in the conclusion of his magisterial study of English enclosure laws.Footnote 110
Second, the rule of law principle can be viewed analytically as incorporating the concept of resource allocation efficiency when law is viewed in terms of “planning” that helps to coordinate behavior—as in Scott Shapiro's work.Footnote 111 Those who stress efficiency as a goal, however, are generally consequentialists. From a consequentialist perspective, the rule of law contributes to resource allocation efficiency and thus economic development by increasing transparency, preventing corruption, and reducing political risk.Footnote 112 Once again, it does not do so from a one-sided focus on investment promotion, but rather from a broader social welfare perspective. Indeed, some empirical evidence shows that, in most contexts, decreased risk in a country's political and legal system—including indicators for law and order—correlates with higher levels of investment.Footnote 113
Third, the rule of law links analytically with the concept of peace by stressing the use of law to resolve conflicts in lieu of power. To turn to a consequentialist perspective, the rule of law can reduce international conflict that otherwise arises when state authorities seize foreign investor property or otherwise deny foreign investors justice. Democratic peace theory provides evidence that democracies grounded in the rule of law are less likely to go to war against each other.Footnote 114 Once more, the rule of law principle does not have a one-sided focus on investors—i.e., focusing on a private right of standing to depoliticize investment disputes—but rather one that encompasses all stakeholders in the investment process.
From a socio-legal perspective, the ultimate challenge for the rule of law is its implementation in practice, which will be mediated by social institutions and legal culture. Because law is frequently ambiguous, often involving the interplay of standards, rules, and exceptions, the application of the rule of law will always be contested.Footnote 115 No legal process is “discretion-free” because law's meaning is mediated through the operation of institutions and interactions involving people. Thus, any meaningful understanding of the rule of law must be based on cultures of practice embedded in institutions.
One of the disconnects in the field of ISDS is that proponents focus on the need for investment arbitration because of challenges with the domestic rule of law, while opponents focus on the failure of ISDS to adhere to rule-of-law standards. Yet, both of these mechanisms are subject to severe imperfections. Thus, any meaningful choice between them from a rule-of-law perspective must engage with a comparison of their trade-offs, along with those of other institutional alternatives. This calls for comparative institutional analysis.
III. The Framework: Comparative Institutional Analysis
However one frames the goals of investment law, those goals must be pursued through institutional mechanisms involving interested actors and different decision-making processes.Footnote 116 Thus, goal choice must be complemented by institutional analysis, whatever the goal may be. For institutional analysis, the key question is: compared to what? Neil Komesar powerfully developed comparative institutional analysis and applied it to U.S. domestic law.Footnote 117 Other scholars have applied the framework to European Union law and WTO law, but, to our knowledge, not explicitly to international investment law.Footnote 118 We do so here.
In critiquing or advocating a particular institutional choice, one should not focus on the defects of a single institution while failing to apply the same rigor to its alternatives. Institutions should rather be assessed from a comparative perspective, one that avoids ideal characterizations in favor of analysis that takes account of real-life institutional pathologies. Just as Ronald Coase labeled economic analyses that compare an existing institution (say the legislative process) with an “ideal” alternative (say the market) as “blackboard economics,”Footnote 119 much international legal scholarship similarly fails to compare institutional alternatives, especially legal processes, that take account of their real-world complexity.
A more realistic assessment of the possible approaches for resolving investment disputes should take account of three central points: first, that the pursuit of any normative goal is mediated by social decision-making processes; second, that these decision-making processes are biased in different ways because of the dynamics of participation within them; and third, that any meaningful public policy analysis must involve comparative institutional analysis of real-world (rather than ideal) alternatives. The key is to assess institutional alternatives comparatively. To do so, one looks at such factors as numbers, complexity, and per capita stakes that shape the dynamics of participation. One then assesses the implications of these dynamics on different forms of bias in institutional decision-making.
A. Participation: Numbers, Complexity, and Per Capita Stakes
A focus on participation in institutional decision-making processes should address both the benefits and costs of participation. Understanding the role of numbers, complexity, and per capita stakes is critical for this analysis. Where there are large numbers of affected individuals who have low per capita stakes, serious collective action problems arise. The benefits may be large in aggregate, but they are not large enough for individuals to attend closely to complex issues. Applied to international investment law, this analysis suggests that individuals are unlikely to organize in opposition to expansive investor protections or to ISDS, whether based on an investment contract, a national law, or an international treaty. In contrast, investors have high per capita stakes in investment projects, which creates the incentive for them to assess benefits and costs. Investors thus may deploy significant resources to shape investment law norms and their application. They are, in sum, well-positioned to lobby for investment protection ex ante and to litigate for favorable interpretations and compensation ex post.Footnote 120
The organization of interests in relation to institutional decision-making has ex ante and ex post dimensions—involving dynamics of participation before and after a dispute arises. The investing firm often has much better information regarding environmental and social risks at stake from a prospective investment, but it may not disclose them. After harms become evident, organizing becomes less demanding for affected communities. This dynamic particularly occurs with local decision-making, where numbers are smaller and so it is easier for individuals to overcome collective action problems when harms become salient.
Organized groups—what Komesar calls “catalytic subgroups”—may have interests in common with the local majority and spur their increased participation. These groups can publicize harms and rally residents to oppose investment projects and place pressure on government officials.Footnote 121 Today, the development of social media can assist their mobilization efforts. International investment dispute settlement thus has analogues with local government decisions since disputes can pit outsider investors against a local community. This local “majority” may, in turn, not take account of the broader social and development concerns of the province or nation, much less the costs imposed on a foreign investor with high sunk costs.Footnote 122 Seen from this perspective, it is not surprising that a number of ISDS cases involve municipalities denying or cancelling permits to operate locally.Footnote 123
B. Decision-making: Minoritarian and Majoritarian Bias
Institutional decision-making inevitably involves the push and pull of different forces in light of the dynamics of participation. These forces give rise to different forms of minoritarian and majoritarian bias.Footnote 124 Minoritarian bias appears when well-organized, discrete interests shape policy. In investment law, this could involve a foreign investor colluding with a domestic government official or, alternatively, a domestic business seeking an advantage over a foreign investor. Majoritarian bias, in contrast, appears when the many oppress the few, imposing higher costs on them.
Assessing these different forms of bias requires a benchmark, which we view in terms of weighing the welfare of all stakeholders equally. While some law-and-economics scholars see the benchmark objectively in terms of resource allocation efficiency, an external, objective assessment becomes difficult, if not impossible, when goals are incommensurate, as they invariably are with public policy. Our focus thus centers on participation in social decision-making processes. From a law-and-economics perspective, participation and social welfare are closely related since, as Komesar writes, “participation is the heart of key economics concepts such as transaction costs, externalities and resource allocation efficiency.”Footnote 125
These different forms of bias in participation in social decision-making processes have distinct dynamics and impacts in the investment law context. For example, minoritarian bias favoring foreign investors may adversely affect domestic stakeholder interests because of adverse environmental and social impacts and other externalities. In contrast, majoritarian bias may adversely affect foreign investors but have different short- and long-term effects on domestic stakeholders. In the short term, domestic politics might favor reneging on a contractual obligation or triggering an expropriation when a country is faced with large budget deficits or immediate resource needs.Footnote 126 However, these actions could have long-term adverse effects on a country's ability to attract capital.
Schools of scholarship often reflect particular ideological predispositions and accordingly tend to focus on biases in particular institutions. For example, public choice approaches focus on minoritarian bias in political processes, assessing the power of the few to shape decision-making, resulting in discrimination and regulatory capture.Footnote 127 Scholars working in this vein often favor the use of market processes to avoid these biases (think, for instance, of much of the scholarship in international trade law). A comparative institutional analysis reveals, however, that market processes also may be skewed because most affected actors are dormant, disorganized, uninformed, or misled. Indeed, were markets to function effectively, competition for investment capital could discipline governmental decision-makers, obviating the need for international investment law in the first instance.
Rights claims can trigger judicial intervention against regulatory decision-making to protect minoritarian interests against majorities. Such intervention may involve a single investor with high per capita stakes on one side and large groups with low per capita stakes on the other. Where they overcome collective action problems, these groups can press officials to impose high costs on sunk investments through ex post regulations or expansive interpretations of existing ones. Investors may have been in a powerful position in drafting contracts and lobbying for regulations ex ante because of their higher per capita stakes compared to the general public, which faced significant information and organizational costs regarding a proposed project. The project's opponents, however, can become more powerful ex post after the investment was made and its ensuing costs became apparent.
Judicial processes can help correct for majoritarian biases by offering the advantage of evenhandedness and legal reasoning—hallmarks of the rule of law. Yet, courts too are subject to limitations and other biases. Judicial processes are expensive to use on a case-by-case basis, thus favoring parties with financial means and high per capita stakes. Judicial processes may thus favor investors who hire sophisticated lawyers to shape the interpretation of open-ended provisions and create favorable legal doctrines over time. In this way, the “haves” may come out ahead in adjudication.Footnote 128 Judicial processes, moreover, have limited resources to handle the range of social conflicts. In short, they involve high access costs and limits of scale given the mass of decisions affecting investments. Judicial processes, moreover, can be remote from the public so that they may be less able to integrate information and balance competing concerns than political processes. International courts particularly face information costs regarding domestic concerns, potentially giving rise to different forms of bias.Footnote 129 Much criticism of ISDS, for example, contends that large multinational corporations, allied with the arbitration bar, bring aggressive claims to chill regulation that would otherwise serve the public interest.Footnote 130 In addition, institutional mechanisms vary in their cost effectiveness in resolving disputes, which needs to be assessed.
Since all institutional processes are imperfect, they are generally distrusted; but they are distrusted in different ways. The creation of investment rights implies distrust of national government, as well as markets. BITs imply a distrust of domestic law. The turn to ISDS implies distrust of domestic courts. The use of balancing tests by ISDS tribunals implies a distrust of political processes and markets. In turn, the proposal for a multilateral investment court system implies distrust of ISDS. This parade of institutional distrust is not surprising, since each institutional alternative is imperfect. For any meaningful policy analysis, however, their imperfections need to be compared and contrasted.
Whatever the goals, and however they are characterized, comparative institutional analysis is required because institutional processes mediate the pursuit of such goals. As Komesar writes, “[i]t is institutional choice that connects goals with their legal and public policy results.”Footnote 131 In weighing different institutional alternatives, the issue of participation, shaped by numbers and per capita stakes, is always central. Biases exist in all institutions, but they differ in degree and kind. Only after comparative institutional analysis should choices be made.
IV. Institutional Alternatives and Investment Law
An analysis of institutional alternatives for handling unfair treatment, discrimination, and expropriation of foreign direct investments should include not only the range of plausible adjudicatory options, but also non-adjudicatory mechanisms. We apply comparative institutional analysis to assess six types of such options: (1) market mechanisms; (2) political mechanisms; (3) domestic dispute settlement mechanisms; (4) independent interstate adjudicatory mechanisms; (5) international adjudicatory mechanisms as substitutes for domestic adjudication; and (6) international adjudicatory mechanisms as complements of domestic adjudication. We explain the trade-offs of each of these institutional alternatives in relation to the goals of investment law, on the one hand, and in light of biases of participation in decision-making, on the other.
A. Market Mechanisms
1. Reputation, contract, and insurance
The relative superiority of adjudication in relation to market mechanisms to ensure just treatment of foreign investors is not immediately evident, especially once one takes into account the economic, political, and social costs of litigation. These costs are particularly salient when companies can deploy the threat of international arbitration under BITs to “chill” regulatory initiatives. In such cases, to borrow from Brian Tamanaha, we risk seeing “the rule of some groups over others by and through the law,” more than a “rule of law that furthers the common good.”Footnote 132 In the discussion that follows, we address the trade-offs of three market mechanisms—reputation, contract, and political risk insurance—in light of the goals of investment law and the different biases of these mechanisms.
The first market mechanism, reputation, is straightforward. Most states prefer to attract investment at a lower cost. Thus, if a state develops a reputation of high risk for foreign direct investment, investors will require a higher rate of return or will simply forego investing in the state. The market for capital investment thus creates pressure on states to treat foreign direct investment fairly. Indeed, states can, and at times do, enact foreign investment legislation through which they commit to use ISDS in limited ways; in this context, state governments are freer to tailor commitments to their view of state needs than when negotiating a BIT.Footnote 133
The market alone, however, may not induce countries to treat investment fairly. State officials may not consider reputational effects, or the countries’ approaches toward foreign direct investment may change. Tomz shows that investors respond to the reputation of the government in power, and not of the state itself.Footnote 134 The possibility of significant political change can thus make the assessment of reputation fragile, leading to a short-term focus.
Second, investors can bargain with governments on a case-by-case basis and negotiate investment protections by contract, such as with a state-controlled enterprise. In these contracts, the parties may refer disputes to domestic courts, foreign courts, or international arbitration and specify the applicability of domestic, foreign, or international law.Footnote 135 Brazil, for example, has never adopted a BIT with ISDS, but it is among the world's largest recipients of foreign direct investment—in part because investors are able to obtain protection through contracts that provide for arbitration.Footnote 136 As Howse explains, “[a] contractual solution may be superior in many instances as the host state can target the protection to investors that it desires to attract.”Footnote 137
Existing data shows that resource-intensive sectors that require large up-front capital investments are frequent users of ISDS.Footnote 138 Over half of all ISDS cases relate to oil, gas, and mining (25 percent), energy production (17 percent), or water, sanitation, and construction (12 percent)—sectors that require large capital investments.Footnote 139 The irony is that it is precisely in these sectors, comprised of sophisticated multinational companies, where investors are relatively better positioned to resolve the “hold-up” risk through contract (which can provide, inter alia, for international arbitration), instead of relying on broad treaty protections with ISDS. These investors of course prefer the addition of ISDS—which creates a baseline of protection that includes an international remedy from which they can engage in further contracting—but the question is whether ISDS is necessary for them, especially in light of the problems with ISDS discussed below.
Third, because economic actors may be unable to “self-insure” efficiently, including by hedging against risks through diversifying, planning, or contracting, they may turn to the insurance market to reduce non-commercial risk. A market for political risk insurance can protect foreign investors, including against unfair, discriminatory, or expropriatory treatment.Footnote 140 Insurance is often provided by governmental and international bodies (such as the Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC) or the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA)).Footnote 141 These bodies, in turn, can use political and legal mechanisms to press recalcitrant states to comply with their commitments to investors.
There appears to be a renewed interest in returning to these market mechanisms. In the renegotiations of the NAFTA, for example, USTR Lighthizer contended that U.S. investors should rely on political risk insurance if they are concerned about investment risk.Footnote 142 This assertion has particular resonance for the large investors that bring most ISDS claims and are better positioned to purchase political risk insurance.Footnote 143
2. Trade-offs of market mechanisms
Seen from the perspective of investment law's goals, there are trade-offs to these market approaches. As regards fairness and the rule of law, market mechanisms such as reputation and risk insurance permit an investor to bypass court proceedings, effectively delegating these concerns to the market.Footnote 144 Insurance alone, however, should be less effective than adjudication in deterring host government decisions ex ante because it focuses on replacement dollars paid by a third party based on a past event.Footnote 145 Contracting, in contrast, permits the state and investor to define what is fair, subject to a dispute settlement mechanism to enforce the bargain. However, if most contracts provide for international commercial arbitration or a foreign judicial forum for dispute settlement, then there will be fewer incentives for the state to invest in independent, impartial, quality domestic dispute settlement mechanisms. Moreover, contracts and international commercial arbitration lack transparency, providing less assurance that public law concerns will be fairly addressed. As for the goal of interstate conflict avoidance, it is conventionally understood that international judicial processes are better than market approaches in constraining the investor's home state from getting involved when a conflict escalates.Footnote 146
Market mechanisms are typically touted on efficiency grounds. However, contracting and insurance can be costly (because of bargaining and information costs), especially for small- and medium-sized investors. Given relatively fixed transaction costs, small investors are less likely to invest resources to bargain with governments for protections, including choice-of-law and dispute settlement clauses, to shield them against the risks of mistreatment. Where investors are priced out of or otherwise unable to obtain insurance or negotiate contracts, their investment may be deterred, raising the state's cost of capital.Footnote 147 Alternatively, states interested in reducing their cost of capital may invest in domestic institutions to encourage investment, reduce risk insurance premiums, and facilitate contract enforcement. In practice, therefore, market mechanisms may be sufficient in many cases.
For major cross-cutting events such as civil war or economic crises affecting many or all investments, it arguably is preferable to rely on market mechanisms such as political risk insurance and currency and other forms of hedging, rather than ex post adjudication, so that investors take precautions and price risks accordingly. An example is the collapse of the Argentine peso, which affected large numbers of investments in Argentina, and which arguably was a foreseeable risk over the long term given the history of financial crises in that country. As Anne van Aaken writes regarding one famous ISDS decision,
Although the tribunal held in its decision on jurisdiction that “Bilateral Investment Treaties are not insurance policies against bad business judgments,” … insuring bad or at least quite imprudent business judgment is exactly the consequence of the CMS tribunal's decision on the merits.Footnote 148
In terms of bias in participation and decision-making, to the extent that contract and insurance are available only for large investors with high per capita stakes, these mechanisms can give rise to minoritarian bias in favor of those actors in relation to smaller investors, be they foreign or domestic. If market mechanisms fail to spur the development of domestic rule-of-law institutions, there will be ongoing risks of majoritarian and minoritarian biases against investors. However, these mechanisms remain important alternatives (or complements), especially for states concerned with diminution of sovereignty from international adjudicatory mechanisms.
B. Political Mechanisms
1. Negotiation and mediation
Conflicts over the treatment of foreign direct investment can also be resolved through political bargaining, thus avoiding the cost of insurance or adjudication.Footnote 149 Mediation—negotiation facilitated by a neutral third party—seems to be increasingly used in international business generally,Footnote 150 and negotiation has been used to address many investment conflicts.Footnote 151 While such negotiations and mediations often occur informally and without much transparency, some countries are promoting more institutionalized alternatives through treaties. For example, MERCOSUR’s Protocol on Investment Cooperation and Facilitation provides for direct state-to-state negotiations (Article 24) and mediation (Article 23).Footnote 152 These procedures are based on Brazil's model Agreement on Cooperation and Facilitation of Investments (ACFI), which the Brazilian government has promoted as an alternative to traditional BITs.Footnote 153
2. Trade-offs of political mechanisms
Reliance on negotiation and mediation should be less likely to promote broader rule of law practices within domestic governance institutions since conflicts would be resolved in light of political objectives shaped by relative power. Fairness toward affected stakeholders would only be addressed as a function of their representation by states. Negotiations might be conducted in the shadow of the law, but references to the law might be just self-serving, cheap talk. Because of the uncertainty of these processes, they also would less likely advance the goal of reducing the cost of investment capital. These political options, however, could be cheaper since the parties would avoid the high costs associated with litigation.Footnote 154 The host state could then use its resources in other more productive ways.
Although diplomacy may work in some instances, it also can be complex, costly, and opaque. The more difficult that it is to understand channels of influence, the costlier it is for investors to organize for political action. Small- and medium-sized investors are likely to be particularly disadvantaged because they have less political access to state officials—who prioritize the deployment of state resources based on economic weight and systemic importance.Footnote 155 In contrast, well-organized actors with substantial stakes are better positioned to trigger a response from the home state. Thus, when this institutional option is used successfully on behalf of an investor, it may be biased in favor of those investors with substantial stakes, reflecting minoritarian bias. When it fails to benefit an unjustly treated investor, it could reflect majoritarian bias.
C. Domestic Dispute Settlement Mechanisms
1. Courts, specialized processes, and ombudsman offices
Domestic dispute settlement mechanisms are the first (and fallback) option for resolving investment disputes through adjudication if negotiations fail. Domestic law can delegate investment disputes to specialized domestic courts and other institutions because of their expertise and to counter bias against outsiders.Footnote 156 Iraq and Kazakhstan, for example, created specialized investment courts to hear disputes between investors and investment authorities for these reasons.Footnote 157 Other countries use alternative dispute resolution mechanisms, including (more recently) an investment ombudsman office.Footnote 158 Morocco and South Korea mandate institutionalized mediation before a domestic institution—respectively, the Moroccan Investment Development Agency and the Korean Commercial Arbitration Board—prior to adjudication.Footnote 159
Domestic dispute settlement mechanisms can apply international law as part of domestic law. Depending on the state's constitutional system, a domestic court can apply international law directly as part of the domestic legal system or indirectly through domestic implementing legislation.Footnote 160 Thus, a national court or domestic authority may be able to decide the investment dispute by reference to a treaty or customary international law.
2. Trade-offs of domestic dispute settlement mechanisms
Using domestic mechanisms, at least as a first instance, offers comparative advantages. First, the rule of law, broadly understood, depends on qualified, independent, impartial domestic dispute settlement institutions that can address the claims of all affected stakeholders. An advantage of addressing these claims together, including any counterclaims by the state or affected individuals or communities, is that a single forum can hear them. Relatedly, a broader range of actors have access to domestic proceedings so that more voices can be heard by decision-makers, which promotes fairness. Since a single venue would hear the claim, the process also could be more efficient. Domestic institutions are relatively more available to hear smaller cases that are important to smaller investors. International investment law's effectiveness thus is bolstered by domestic mechanisms.Footnote 161 Where a critical mass of actors uses domestic institutions to resolve investment disputes, these institutions can develop expertise and a professional ethos and reputation. Domestic institutions with these characteristics are more likely to be accepted as legitimate venues for resolving claims than a remote international body. This, in turn, can facilitate enforcement and compliance.
The effective use of domestic mechanisms also can help to incentivize investment and support economic growth, thereby reducing a country's cost of capital. A state that wishes to reduce its cost of capital thus has an incentive to invest in domestic institutions to uphold the rule of law. In contrast, automatic resort to international dispute settlement as a substitute for domestic mechanisms could reduce pressure to create national institutions that are independent and can hold governments accountable.Footnote 162
The internationalization of investment disputes, however, is a response to real deficiencies in many judicial systems and concerns over the impartiality of domestic authorities. From the perspective of capital exporting countries, national courts in many developing countries are unable to provide speedy, neutral, and technically competent resolution of investment claims.Footnote 163 In these situations, investors prefer enforcement outside of local institutions to ensure fairness. Historically, developing countries have agreed to these processes in part because of power dynamics, but also often because they know that their domestic judicial systems can fail to provide such assurances.
Domestic mechanisms also are prone to majoritarian bias and minoritarian bias. Local majorities can inflict high costs on investors where a single investor with high per capita stakes is on one side, and, on the other side, are large groups with low per capita stakes. Domestic authorities may not be able to withstand pressure to adopt popular decisions at the investor's expense. At other times, domestic minoritarian interests may convince local authorities to take unfair or discriminatory action against a foreign investor. On the other hand, although one always can find examples of minoritarian bias, many studies find that foreign firms, on average, are treated at least the same or even better than domestic firms, such that the alternative of ISDS provides them with an even greater advantage.Footnote 164 The choice of this option thus depends on context and, once again, its comparison with other institutional alternatives.
D. Independent Interstate Adjudicatory Mechanisms
In the investment context, a state can be sued before an international court or tribunal with jurisdiction when another state asserts diplomatic protection on behalf of its nationals. In espousing an investor's claim, the state operates independently of the investor, which has no direct control over the claim, unlike the other adjudicatory mechanisms we assess. Interstate adjudication of investment disputes generally does not result from acceptance of an international court's jurisdiction before a dispute arises. Rather, states more commonly make arrangements after the conduct at issue occurs by creating ad hoc tribunals or consenting to jurisdiction for a specific case. Nonetheless, permanent bodies such as the ICJ or the WTO have heard some investment-related complaints.
1. Ad hoc tribunals
States have periodically created international claims commissions and ad hoc arbitral tribunals to adjudicate cases involving the seizure and mistreatment of foreign-held property.Footnote 165 In many of these instances, states established a semi-permanent body where only states have standing and control the selection of arbitrators. Some of these tribunals have been created following mediation or peace agreements involving diplomatic efforts and sometimes coercion. The best-known example of interstate ad hoc adjudication of investment disputes because of its duration and number of awards is the Iran-U.S. Claims Tribunal. The tribunal was created pursuant to the Algiers Accords after Iran held U.S. embassy officials as hostages and nationalized the assets of U.S. companies, and the United States, in turn, froze around US$11 billion of Iranian assets held in U.S. banks.Footnote 166 During the 1980s and 1990s, the Iran-U.S. Claims Tribunal created a huge body of investment law jurisprudence that laid important groundwork for ISDS case law.Footnote 167
The United States and Europe have generally stopped espousing investor claims, and, with ISDS, they have little reason to do so.Footnote 168 The United Kingdom, for example, wound up its Foreign Compensation Commission, sending a general message that its investors are on their own (i.e., should rely on BITs) to resolve disputes.Footnote 169 The United States still espouses investor claims, but its policy shifted so that it does not espouse a claim if the investor has other options available, such as before local courts or ISDS. Some states, however, have recently advocated for interstate alternatives to ISDS.Footnote 170 Brazil's ACFI, for example, only provides for state-to-state adjudication, and it does not grant the tribunal jurisdiction to determine damages unless the home and host state consent and only after the investor's withdrawal of damages claims before domestic tribunals.Footnote 171 South Africa's Protection of Investment Act of 2015 provides that the government may consent to state-to-state dispute settlement, rather than ISDS, subject to the exhaustion of local remedies.Footnote 172
2. International courts
Modern BITs have antecedents in FCN treaties, and some of these treaties provided for interstate dispute resolution before the ICJ. Very few cases before the ICJ, however, have involved the treatment of foreign investment. In the Barcelona Traction case, the Court found that the treaty at issue provided limited rights for shareholders, and it set a high bar for legal standing to invoke state responsibility on their behalf.Footnote 173 Capital exporting countries, lobbied by multinational corporations, thus turned to more specialized bodies to resolve investment conflicts.
In 1995, states created the WTO, the multilateral trade organization with a compulsory dispute settlement system. The WTO covers some investment-related disciplines in different agreements. The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) addresses the establishment of a “commercial presence” in WTO members to provide services (i.e., an investment). The Agreement on Trade-Related Investment Measures (TRIMS) prohibits investment measures that favor the use of domestic products over foreign ones, such as through domestic content regulations. The Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) prescribes rules protecting patents, copyrights, trademarks, and other intellectual property. Some WTO members have continued to advocate for additional coverage of investment issues.Footnote 174 Any WTO member can activate the WTO system of interstate adjudication, which does not require the exhaustion of local remedies. Its two-tier process includes an appellate body, which provides a precedent for the EU's proposed multilateral investment court system. Indeed, rather than creating a new international organization with a new secretariat, an investment court could be housed at the WTO, which some favor.Footnote 175
A few WTO disputes have involved investment-related issues, including regarding GATS, TRIMS, and TRIPS, and a few of them were litigated in parallel to ISDS cases.Footnote 176 However, because WTO claims are limited to the WTO covered agreements and because many countries’ commitments under the GATS are limited, WTO cases generally have not addressed the most frequently litigated ISDS claims regarding fair and equitable treatment and expropriation. They rather have involved claims over intellectual property and non-discrimination, especially since BITs and ISDS panels have adopted expansive definitions of “investment.” The most noteworthy case is Australia-Plain Tobacco Packaging where the WTO and ISDS claims were largely analogous, based on an alleged indirect expropriation of a Philip Morris brand (under the BIT claim) and the encumberment of the trademark (under the WTO TRIPS claim).Footnote 177 There also have been parallel ISDS and WTO national treatment cases based on the same government measure, with the WTO cases addressing discrimination against traded goods and the ISDS ones involving discrimination against the foreign investor.Footnote 178 Analogously, there were both WTO and ISDS claims brought against Mexico's telecommunications regulations that favored the Mexican quasi-monopolist Telmex.Footnote 179 More generally, WTO Appellate Body jurisprudence upholding non-discriminatory state regulation has been cited and arguably influenced ISDS cases regarding the need for balance in recognizing a state's right to regulate.Footnote 180
3. Trade-offs of independent interstate adjudicatory mechanisms
These two types of interstate options—ad hoc tribunals and permanent courts—present similar trade-offs, but they also exhibit some important differences. Both permanent and ad hoc bodies can provide some support for adherence to the rule of law, and thus provide some assurance of fair treatment of investors. However, a permanent international court hearing investment claims offers certain advantages over ad hoc dispute settlement. First, it can create greater certainty that claims may be brought, since no further negotiations are needed to create the tribunal. Second, a multilateral dispute settlement mechanism, as under the WTO, can cover the major nations of the world, operate iteratively over time in clarifying and enforcing legal commitments, and thus have more normative authority than ad hoc bodies.Footnote 181 This is particularly the case of an international mechanism with an appeals system, such as the WTO Appellate Body, which has generated a substantial and influential jurisprudence, including regarding a state's right to regulate.Footnote 182 As a result, permanent interstate bodies could better facilitate the diffusion of norms of fairness, helping to enhance rule-of-law accountability in domestic jurisdictions.
Interstate adjudicatory mechanisms both offer benefits and raise concerns because of state control of the process. On the one hand, states may represent the broader interests of their citizens, as opposed to only investor commercial interests. Because interstate alternatives constrain access to dispute settlement, they create an opportunity for states to screen controversial, overly aggressive, or illegitimate claims.Footnote 183 Moreover, this alternative permits states to control the arguments brought before tribunals regarding the interpretation of the treaty they negotiated. This power is important, since in many instances states could be on either side of investment claims—as a defendant or as a complainant espousing a national's claims. Having states act as filters can be beneficial because it eliminates corporate actors’ ability to aggressively pursue adjudication through ISDS—whether to bargain in the law's shadow, counter prospective regulation through the threat of an expensive lawsuit, or to shape the law's interpretation—and can thus be relatively less biased against states and the other stakeholder interests that states represent. Because states retain control of dispute settlement, they can focus on long-term mutual gains, rather than short-term victories in investment disputes.
On the other hand, because the system is state-based, it retains a political/diplomatic dimension and thus does not focus directly on the fair treatment of private parties, nor on enhancing the rule of law in domestic jurisdictions. States may sacrifice a private party's interests and decide not to bring a claim.Footnote 184 In addition, states control the selection of judges, so that the judges in these bodies may have only moderate independence.Footnote 185 Moreover, remedies issued by interstate bodies may not benefit the harmed investor. The primary WTO remedy, for example, is the withdrawal of equivalent concessions by the complaining state, which provides no compensation to the aggrieved private party.Footnote 186 In consequence, investors could be warier about investing in the state in question, potentially increasing that state's cost of capital. Finally, in terms of international relations, this mechanism may be less likely to depoliticize a conflict since the bringing of claims by one state against another could be viewed as an unfriendly, political act, at least more so than when an investor brings the claims on its own.Footnote 187
In terms of participation and bias, because states exercise discretion as to whether to espouse a claim, participation will more likely be skewed in favor of well-connected private parties. States may only espouse claims of nationals that are politically influential and vociferously lobby them. They may only represent claims of large companies, so that small- and medium-sized companies’ claims are sacrificed in the interest of interstate relations, and hence result in minoritarian bias. International adjudicatory bodies (whether permanent or ad hoc) also could exhibit bias in favor of powerful states, such as to ensure their support for the overall system so that it does not collapse.Footnote 188 Yet, once again, the benefits and deficiencies of this alternative must be assessed against those besetting other decision-making processes in light of particular contexts.
E. International Adjudicatory Mechanisms as Substitutes
The proliferation of ISDS cases and large damage awards has catalyzed debates over institutional reform, notably over whether to create a multilateral investment court system. Although both ISDS and such a system could operate as complements to domestic mechanisms, we address the two options as substitutes because that is how they have been proposed and operated.Footnote 189
1. Ad hoc tribunals—ISDS
ISDS is the dominant method for international investment adjudication today. Thousands of BITs provide for it, as do many free trade agreements such as NAFTA. ISDS is a mechanism through which investors may directly obtain damages from states for breaches of international investment law by bringing claims to an arbitral panel.Footnote 190 ICSID provides the main pillar for ISDS, although approximately 39 percent of proceedings take place outside of ICSID, such as through the Permanent Court of Arbitration in the Hague, the Stockholm Chamber of Commerce, and other bodies.Footnote 191 Individual arbitrations have produced awards of over a billion dollars, and numerous awards are in the hundreds of millions.Footnote 192 The awards are binding on the parties and not subject to appeal or to any other checks except on very limited grounds.Footnote 193
2. Trade-offs of ISDS
ISDS offers many institutional advantages, especially for investors. Compared to domestic mechanisms, ISDS guarantees foreign investors access to a specialized adjudicatory process that is independent of national authorities. It provides an alternative where domestic systems lack reliable, quality, impartial courts. Compared to the interstate alternative, the investor has a private right of action and does not depend on the state to espouse its claim. It is thus viewed as a more legal and less political process than interstate dispute settlement.Footnote 194 Accordingly, ISDS should be more attractive to investors, although the investor must cover its share of the cost of arbitration.
To the extent that ISDS provides greater assurances to investors that they will be fairly treated in accordance with basic rule-of-law protections, ISDS could help states to attract investment, thus contributing to resource allocation efficiency and aggregate national welfare. In addition, from the perspective of interstate relations, ISDS compartmentalizes conflicts between states by providing investors with legal standing to bring claims. To some, it thus appears superior from the perspective of interstate conflict avoidance.Footnote 195
ISDS is also subject to disadvantages in terms of investment law's goals. From the perspective of fairness, many contend that ISDS is biased in favor of investors.Footnote 196 From the perspective of the rule of law, since ISDS decisions are made on an ad hoc basis and are not subject to appeal, they have resulted in many inconsistencies and contradictions, such that like cases are not decided alike.Footnote 197 From the perspective of resource allocation efficiency, since countries balance investment promotion against other social welfare goals, if ISDS is biased against other state social welfare policies, then any additional investment is not optimal.Footnote 198 Moreover, ISDS jurisprudence generated by investor claims, has created considerable uncertainty, both because of its inconsistencies and because it frequently calls into question contractual commitments that are overridden by BIT claims.Footnote 199 In addition, empirical studies question whether BITs with ISDS, in fact, lead to greater foreign direct investment.Footnote 200 From the perspective of depoliticization, investors at times bring claims that implicate highly sensitive domestic policies, thus increasing conflict and political tension.
Perhaps most importantly, the rule of law ultimately depends on domestic governance, but ISDS has operated as a substitute for local courts. Article 26 of the ICSID Convention does not require “exhaustion of local administrative or judicial remedies” “unless otherwise stated” in a treaty, and in practice most BITs do not require it.Footnote 201 Indeed, for years ICSID highlighted the importance of abstention from domestic courts as “essential to the proper implementation” of ISDS.Footnote 202 In fact, many BITs contain a fork-in-the-road provision that can be fatal to the use of investor-state arbitration under a BIT.Footnote 203 Where ISDS discourages a relationship of complementarity with domestic courts, it can reduce the pressure for domestic rule-of-law reforms.Footnote 204 It thus tends to promote exit (from domestic legal systems) over voice (in domestic law reform debates).Footnote 205
In terms of participation and bias, adjudication can offer the advantage of evenhandedness and legal reasoning to counter potential majoritarian bias against investors. ISDS, however, involves high access costs, is removed from mass publics, and is commonly charged with failure to appropriately balance competing interests, in part because of the inability of states and other stakeholders to raise claims and counterclaims against investors.Footnote 206 Moreover, unlike judges, arbitrators in ISDS are nominated by the parties. This selection process may shape their dispositions, reflecting different forms of bias—categorized as selection, compensation, and affiliation bias.Footnote 207 Some arbitrators represent and consult for private clients in their legal practice, and thus may face conflicts of interest.Footnote 208 Structurally, since the ISDS system is highly remunerative for private practitioners, and since the arbitrators are paid on a case-by-case basis (and by the hour), the arbitrators have an incentive to ensure the future flow of claims. ISDS thus can lead to minoritarian bias in favor of investors, especially those that are well-organized, because they have high per capita stakes, compared to other stakeholders that are numerous but disorganized due to their low per capita stakes.
3. International courts—multilateral investment court system
Because of the criticisms of ISDS, the EU and many commentators have advocated for the creation of a specialized court containing an appellate body. What the EU proposal and ISDS have in common is a private right of standing to bring international claims directly against states.Footnote 209 They differ in their form—mainly, ad hoc arbitration versus a two-tier system with a standing court and appeals court. At the outset, it is important to note that if a multilateral international court system is created, as through the UNCITRAL process, it could potentially depart from the EU proposed model in significant ways.Footnote 210 Analysis should thus include how the EU proposal may be adapted.Footnote 211
The EU proposal is not the first for a permanent investment court.Footnote 212 Notably, the 1974 Convention of the Settlement of Investment Disputes between Host States of Arab Investments and Nationals of Other Arab States created the Arab Court of Investment, which is now active.Footnote 213 Unlike this regional system, however, the system pursued by the EU bilaterally and multilaterally has the potential to extend beyond a discrete geographical region and be widely used.
The EU is incrementally creating a base for such a system through signing bilateral agreements, such as with Canada, Mexico, Singapore, and Vietnam,Footnote 214 while the EU continues to promote the multilateral investment court system in parallel. These agreements are pending ratification by each of the EU member states, which will take time, and Belgium has requested the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) to issue an opinion regarding the compatibility with EU law of CETA's provisions regarding an investment court system.Footnote 215 Under these agreements, claims are to be heard by three-member divisions of a permanent court, which would replace the system of party appointments.Footnote 216 The court's decision is subject to appeal before a tribunal comprised of six members who must “have demonstrated expertise in public international law.”Footnote 217 The grounds for appeal include errors of law and manifest errors of fact, in addition to the grounds provided in Article 52 of the ICSID Convention.Footnote 218 The appeal tribunal would have the power to “modify or reverse” the panel's decision or remand it for further consideration. The contracting states would select the members of the court and appeal tribunal, who would be paid a regular salary, enjoy security of tenure for a fixed, non-renewable term (around four to five years), and be subject to a set of ethical obligations to ensure independence and impartiality.Footnote 219 If the multilateral investment court system draws from this model, many further procedural details remain to be determined by the parties that choose to join it. The EU's treaties, such as CETA, commit the parties to apply a multilateral mechanism once established.Footnote 220
4. Trade-offs of the multilateral investment court system
As regards fairness, some commentators contend that a multilateral investment court system would be less fair for investors because states would control the nomination of judges and thus the judges would favor states.Footnote 221 Other commentators object to the notion that fairness requires allowing private parties to choose their own judges when suing states, given the broader public policy interests are at stake.Footnote 222 Arguably, when selecting permanent judges ex ante rather than ad hoc arbitrators ex post, treaty parties have a greater incentive to internalize their interests as capital-importers and -exporters and thus pick balanced judges, rather than pro-state or pro-investor ones, who are committed to upholding the treaty parties’ agreement.Footnote 223 For many skeptics of ISDS, a court should be better positioned to balance investor rights against other public policy goals, as reflected in the principle of a state's right to regulate. In addition, a court with an appellate mechanism is more likely to treat like cases alike, so that investors’ claims will be treated more consistently (especially where the text of the applicable legal instruments is the same).
The proposed multilateral investment court system also provides greater opportunities than ISDS for repeat interaction with national courts. These interactions are more likely to give rise to a common understanding of legal obligations. If that occurs, then the court may be better positioned to advance rule-of-law norms within domestic governance. Nonetheless, since the proposed system is structured as a substitute for domestic courts (subject to reservations), it also is less likely than complementary mechanisms to place pressure on national governments to ensure the independence, impartiality, and quality of their domestic dispute settlement systems.Footnote 224
Commentators also contend that a multilateral court system would be less biased than ISDS in favor of major powers, and in particular the United States. Gus Van Harten, for example, notes that under ICSID, the authority to appoint arbitrators that the parties do not designate, such as the chair of the tribunal, is vested in an official who is close to the U.S. government.Footnote 225 The Convention empowers the chairman of ICSID’s Administrative Council (i.e., the president of the World Bank, who always has been a U.S. national) to select from among a roster of arbitrators the remaining arbitrator(s). In practice, this function is performed on the recommendation of ICSID’s secretary-general, whom a former (acting) secretary-general of ICSID has accused of “paying heed” to the United States and other rich countries.Footnote 226 Interestingly, the United States has never lost an ISDS case.Footnote 227
From the perspective of resource allocation efficiency, if a permanent court is more deferential toward states because states appoint the judges, then, in theory, investors could be warier of investing, raising a state's cost of capital. Yet, for investment protection to be optimal, states should balance foreign investment with other social welfare goals, and tribunals should not privilege investor protection over those goals. Moreover, there is little reason to believe, and no empirical evidence to substantiate, that rational investors would be less likely to invest under a multilateral investment court system rather than ISDS—although the court could face backlog problems since it cannot expand the number of panels in response to a large number of new claims as the ISDS regime. In addition, although maintaining a permanent court has costs, ISDS may be just as expensive, especially since annulment proceedings are frequently used. Thus, institutional costs should be given limited weight in deciding between them (especially if the costs can be transferred partially to the disputing parties), although they could be a factor in relation to other alternatives.Footnote 228
The proposed multilateral investment court system should have similar, although potentially not as robust, positive effects as ISDS on depoliticizing disputes. Permitting investors to take disputes directly could depoliticize them as compared to having them resolved through diplomatic confrontation. Yet, because states control the appointment of the judges, the process could become politicized, as seen in the crisis besetting the WTO's Appellate Body.Footnote 229 Members of the international investment law community fear a similar attack on a potential investment court.
In terms of bias, depending on implementation details regarding the cost of access, transparency, and the process of nominating adjudicators, the proposed multilateral investment court system could better balance investors’ legitimate expectations against state regulatory goals. It thus has the potential to correct some of the minoritarian biases associated with ISDS while also helping to counter majoritarian biases in domestic decision-making. Nonetheless, use of a permanent court would remain expensive, thus favoring those with high per capita stakes, such as large investors. If such potential bias raises concerns, the question remains: compared to what?
F. International Adjudicatory Mechanisms as Complements
A final adjudicative alternative is a system of complementarity under which domestic and international dispute settlement processes are linked. This alternative prioritizes the use and development of domestic institutions (courts or otherwise), which are first given the opportunity to decide the matter. An international adjudicatory body acts as a backdrop, which, depending on how the process is structured, potentially overrules, takes account, or provides guidance for the domestic determinations.
There are multiple ways to design complementary processes. We present three examples of existing international mechanisms that could motivate experimentation: (1) direct review of domestic administrative or judicial decisions by an international panel, as reflected in NAFTA Chapter 19; (2) independent review of compliance with international law commitments after the exhaustion of domestic judicial procedures, as before the European Court of Human Rights (ECtHR); and (3) referrals by national courts to an international court, as under the preliminary reference procedure of the CJEU. We then briefly note other variants that could be considered, such as abstention and certification, which are used in other contexts, including some federal jurisdictions.
1. International review of domestic decisions
One option involving complementarity is to provide for domestic decision-making up to a certain stage, subject to review by an international adjudicatory body. NAFTA review of antidumping and countervailing duty decisions by national administrative bodies provides an example. Chapter 19 of the trade agreement provides that the state of nationality of the foreign exporter may, or upon the exporter's request shall, request the establishment of a binational panel to review the final determination issued by the relevant authority of the NAFTA party.Footnote 230 The binational panel, composed of five members from the two countries involved, can affirm, overrule, or remand agency determinations. The decisions are binding within the domestic jurisdiction and cannot be appealed to domestic courts. The process is complemented by an extraordinary challenge procedure where a NAFTA party can challenge a binational panel ruling on limited grounds, such as for manifestly exceeding its powers.Footnote 231
Under NAFTA Chapter 19, each party applies its domestic law, which it is free to amend at any time provided that its domestic law complies with WTO rules.Footnote 232 WTO law, in turn, is enforced through interstate dispute settlement, which helps to clarify the meaning of the provisions.Footnote 233 The binational panel's determination focuses exclusively on the correct application of the law by the domestic authority conducting the investigation, creating an international check on the domestic decision-making process. As a result, binational panels replace judicial review of national administrative decisions by domestic courts.
In theory, parties could adapt this process to provide for first-level judicial review before a national court, subject to appeal before an international tribunal. The ability to appeal judicial decisions to an international panel can check bias in national decision-making, but it also raises sovereignty concerns. Indeed, the current U.S. administration wants to terminate NAFTA Chapter 19, and others in the United States have questioned Chapter 19's constitutionality.Footnote 234 Similarly, Belgium has asked the CJEU to issue an opinion on the compatibility of the investment court system under CETA with EU law, and the CJEU held in March 2018 that the provisions for ISDS in a BIT between EU member states are incompatible with EU law.Footnote 235 The sovereignty concerns would become even more salient were an international body to overrule a domestic court's application of domestic law. Reflecting this concern, India's new model BIT provides that arbitral tribunals shall not have jurisdiction “to re-examine any legal issue which has been finally settled by any judicial authority of the Host State.”Footnote 236
2. International claims after domestic proceedings
A second option is to permit a private party to bring a claim before an international adjudicatory body under international law, but only after exhausting domestic remedies. This approach differs from the first in that the international adjudicator does not apply domestic law, nor does it directly review or reverse a domestic administrative or judicial finding. Rather, the international mechanism applies international law and commences proceedings only after domestic law processes are completed.
The ECtHR exemplifies this approach. The court has jurisdiction to hear disputes filed by private parties as well as states under the European Convention of Human Rights (ECHR) and its Protocols against any of the forty-seven members of the Council of Europe. The ECtHR has heard investment law claims under the right to “property” enshrined in Article 1 of Protocol No. 1 of the ECHR.Footnote 237 Most notably, the ECtHR heard a challenge relating to Russia's nationalization of the Yukos oil company, issuing a €1.87 billion award against Russia in 2014—the largest award in the court's history—although Russia has yet to pay it.Footnote 238
Article 35 of the ECHR requires the exhaustion of local remedies before a party may initiate a claim before the court.Footnote 239 The rationale for the rule is to afford domestic authorities the opportunity to prevent or correct an alleged international law violation. A domestic court can, in the process, apply the international standard and internalize it as part of domestic law. When praising the rule of exhaustion of local remedies, Louis Sohn and Richard Baxter emphasized the benefits of putting domestic courts in the front line to oversee compliance with international law obligations and enhance international law's effectiveness.Footnote 240
The use of exhaustion represents a form of “subsidiarity,” a principle which favors decision-making at the local level where possible.Footnote 241 The ECtHR complements the subsidiarity principle with the principle of a “margin of appreciation,” under which the court grants local decision-makers a degree of discretion in applying ECHR standards in light of local contexts and conditions.Footnote 242 The court varies its application of the margin as a function of the sufficiency and effectiveness of domestic procedures and remedies.Footnote 243 In doing so, it arguably provides an incentive for domestic authorities to improve the domestic rule of law.
3. Interpretation at the request of national courts
Under a third option, domestic courts could be required to submit questions to an international adjudicatory body concerning an issue of international law that has not been clearly settled. The response by the international body—likely a court—is binding as a matter of law. Unlike under the first and second complementarity options, it is the national court that ultimately resolves the dispute between the parties. The national court decides all factual issues and it applies international law (as clarified by the international court) to the facts of the case.
The European Union uses such an approach for EU law, which is part of the national law of EU member states. National courts may (and courts of final review must) ask the CJEU for a preliminary ruling whenever a question of EU law is raised unless the CJEU has already pronounced on an identical matter or there is no reasonable doubt about the appropriate interpretation.Footnote 244 The European Union backs this system with a parallel procedure pursuant to which member states or the European Commission can challenge a state's failure to comply with EU law.Footnote 245
4. Other variants of complementarity
The complementarity mechanisms described above could be tailored to the investment context. For example, a treaty could require the use of local remedies for a significant period of time before international adjudication can be triggered—such as the five-year period prescribed in India's new model BITFootnote 246—and an arbitral tribunal could be granted the discretion to stay the arbitration and extend such period where appropriate. An investment treaty also could grant private parties the right, following the exhaustion of local remedies, to petition an international commission that is empowered to bring investment claims on their behalf before an international court. The American Convention on Human Rights, which contains a right to property, includes such a mechanism.Footnote 247
Other variants could build on domestic federal jurisdictions and private international law. For example, an international tribunal could refer a question of domestic law that arises in an investment dispute to a domestic court. Some jurisdictions, such as the United States, use an analogous mechanism whereby a federal court abstains from deciding a matter where state law is unclear until it is clarified by a state court, or refers the question to the state's highest court (a procedure known as “certification”).Footnote 248 Many well-known investment disputes illustrate how this procedure could be useful. For example, in his dissent in Bilcon v. Canada, Donald McRae found that the tribunal decided an issue under Canadian law that should have been decided by Canadian courts.Footnote 249 A similar issue arose in the Metalclad case, which involved the power of local Mexican authorities under the Mexican constitution.Footnote 250 In private international law, national courts also can stay proceedings out of international comity while another court decides the issues, basing their decisions on such factors as respect for the acts of foreign courts, fairness to disputants, and efficiency.Footnote 251
Finally, one can imagine less formal means that facilitate the use of domestic dispute settlement in the first instance. NAFTA gives investors up to three years to trigger arbitration, and thus investors may pursue local remedies until that time.Footnote 252 CETA goes further. Like NAFTA, it establishes a three-year statute of limitations if no domestic remedies are pursued. However, if domestic remedies are pursued, then the investor has two years to commence arbitration after they are completed, subject to a maximum of ten years from the initial measure.Footnote 253 In each case, once an investor initiates arbitration, it may no longer bring or continue its claims for damages before a domestic administrative tribunal or court. In this way, investors are granted time to resolve matters within domestic legal systems without pressure to trigger ISDS. There is some evidence that this mechanism may lead to more reliance on domestic courts than fork-in-the-road provisions under which an investor must exclusively use either local remedies or ISDS.Footnote 254
5. Trade-offs of complementarity mechanisms
The above examples of complementarity operate in different ways, but they uncover common lessons. Most importantly, complementarity mechanisms prioritize the enhancement of the rule of law within domestic jurisdictions. They recognize domestic authorities as the primary guardians of achieving the rule of law and fairness toward investors and other constituencies, but subject to an international accountability mechanism. In the process, they can enhance legal certainty and uniform application of the law. By empowering domestic courts to oversee compliance with legal obligations (which directly or indirectly reflect international law ones), complementarity mechanisms can broaden international law's reach.Footnote 255 There is some (at least preliminary) empirical evidence that they do so better than the alternative of using international tribunals as substitutes.Footnote 256 These mechanisms can provide better assurance to all investors—large and small, foreign and domestic—thus reducing the cost of investment capital within the state. If the processes avoid significantly greater delay than the ISDS or proposed international court system—for instance, through tight standardized schedules (as under the WTO)—they should provide assurance for foreign investors. In addition, because complementarity mechanisms trigger interaction between national and international bodies, they can facilitate greater congruence between international and national norms.Footnote 257 As a result, states may be less inclined to politicize a conflict.
There are nonetheless potential disadvantages with this alternative. Some argue that there is a level of expertise lost through the application of international law by domestic judges with general jurisdiction.Footnote 258 Others contend that empowering domestic adjudicatory processes to apply international law will catalyze new judicial politics domestically.Footnote 259 Increased interaction could lead to politicization and friction between international and domestic courts as well, especially if an international tribunal were to expressly overrule a domestic legal system's highest court.Footnote 260 Complementarity mechanisms—depending on their design—also could create significant delay and increase the cost of dispute settlement.Footnote 261 If so, this could prejudice investors, which could be deterred from investing.Footnote 262
From the vantage of comparative institutional analysis, the potential complexity, delay, and increased cost of complementarity mechanisms create a risk of minoritarian bias, since large investors with large stakes are better positioned than others to use such mechanisms. In addition, because investors no longer would have direct access to an international body, some could relinquish justified claims because of the increased costs, and thus local majoritarian bias would not be countered.
The key disadvantage of these mechanisms is that their effectiveness depends on the good faith of national courts. Reference procedures, for example, depend on whether national courts refer questions to the international body, since such referrals may not be under the parties’ control. If national courts are not independent of the government, then references may not occur. Exhaustion of local remedies rules function only when domestic courts provide real access to justice, as opposed to endless delay in favor of the state. Without some level of trust in national courts, complementarity mechanisms could play into the hands of states that use the prospect of endless delay to extract concessions from aggrieved investors.
Nonetheless, complementarity mechanisms facilitate the ability of all stakeholders to advance claims and counterclaims regarding an investment dispute because they prioritize the use of domestic mechanisms. They thus can be less one-sided and asymmetric than international adjudicatory mechanism such as ISDS or a multilateral investment court system used as substitutes. In this way, they can better protect against potential minoritarian bias in favor of high-stakes investors, which is a common criticism of ISDS. As counter-majoritarian institutions, domestic courts can also check majoritarian biases in domestic decision-making, while being better situated to account for domestic local contexts.
As previously discussed, domestic courts can also be subject to bias. In the case of complementarity mechanisms, however, these biases can be checked. An international tribunal is held in reserve to help support and assure that domestic processes function as intended. In this way, complementarity mechanisms can address the relative deficiencies of relying solely on domestic mechanisms or, alternatively, solely on international adjudicatory processes.
In the end, the effectiveness of complementarity mechanisms depends on the existence of some level of judicial independence and impartiality in the domestic jurisdiction, combined with some level of trust across the domestic/international divide. Where these conditions are present, complementarity mechanisms can be both fair and effective. Moreover, they can work dynamically to enhance rule-of-law protections over time. Where these conditions are lacking, then complementarity mechanisms could be dysfunctional or at least increase the cost of dispute settlement. As in all cases, the imperfections of these complementary options must be weighed against those of other institutional alternatives.
V. Conclusion
While institutional choice is always contextual and thus difficult, comparative institutional analysis is essential because all institutional options are imperfect and subject to trade-offs. Market options may not be available in many situations, especially for small- and medium-sized investors. Domestic mechanisms may not be independent or impartial, and thus lack basic rule-of-law protections. Diplomacy tends to favor powerful states, as well as influential firms that lobby them. Interstate dispute settlement can politicize disputes and still be tilted in favor of powerful actors, whether they be states or large corporations that have privileged access to state officials.
For these reasons, many states turned to what is now the most frequently used mechanism—ISDS—but it too has many deficiencies. The system of appointment of arbitrators creates perverse incentives; there is no appeal mechanism to provide for consistency and a check on poor decisions; and inconsistent decisions made by ad hoc tribunals limit the law's expressive value. A multilateral investment court system seems better on many counts. Yet it also is remote from domestic publics and its decisions could be resisted on sovereignty grounds.
In sum, it is difficult to decide in the abstract which institutional option is preferable. The primary goal, in our view, should be supporting the domestic rule of law. Thus, we highlight the importance of complementarity as an institutional option, an attribute that neither the current ISDS system nor the proposed multilateral investment court system prioritizes, although they could be adapted to do so, including through the current UNCITRAL reform process. From this perspective, national courts should be the first-line actors for resolving disputes, and other institutional mechanisms should provide incentives for enhancing the rule of law.
Contexts differ across states, and choices should depend on those contexts. Where basic rule-of-law norms are protected, the costs of an additional international system of review may not be worthwhile. Rather, reliance may be better placed on national courts, backed by market mechanisms. Where a state, in contrast, lacks independent, impartial, quality courts, an international mechanism that provides for investor standing to bring claims is of much greater importance. In some contexts, states may prefer not to include a system of exhaustion of local remedies so as to streamline the process. A state can then provide greater assurance to investors. In this context, a permanent court with an appellate mechanism appears to be a superior model to ISDS because it would more likely be attentive to a state's public policy interests, and it would provide for greater consistency and coherence across decisions.
Including national courts in decision-making offers advantages for building the domestic rule of law dynamically over time. For transitional states, ones where courts are developing in their professionalism and independence, a system of complementarity seems more appropriate. When rule-of-law norms are advanced through international law and become embedded in domestic governance, they can contribute to the creation of a broader transnational legal order.Footnote 263
We do not claim to have found an institutional option that is best across all contexts or through time. Adopting a legal realist perspective,Footnote 264 the primary goal of this Article is to present and apply an analytic framework that helps to clarify the trade-offs of different institutional options for international investment law. The option chosen will be a function of context involving particular factors, such as a state's capital endowment, market size, ideology, institutional development, and historical legacy.Footnote 265 The tailoring of institutional choice can be met by what Roberts describes as ongoing pluralism and flexibility in the architecture of institutional mechanisms.Footnote 266 Looking forward, our analysis reveals that the international investment regime should not simply rely on ISDS. Nor should it be replaced with a multilateral investment court system that applies to all countries unless such system provides for flexibility, such as through opt out and opt in provisions.Footnote 267 Maintaining flexibility will be key, a flexibility that permits states facing different challenges to select from a menu of imperfect international alternatives in light of their trade-offs. That flexibility should include experimentation with different complementarity mechanisms.
Target article
Imperfect Alternatives: Institutional Choice and the Reform of Investment Law
Related commentaries (7)
A Trinity Analytical Framework for ISDS Reform
Control, Capacity, and Legitimacy in Investment Treaty Arbitration
Introduction to the Symposium on Sergio Puig and Gregory Shaffer, “Imperfect Alternatives: Institutional Choice and the Reform of Investment Law,” and Anthea Roberts, “Incremental, Systemic, and Paradigmatic Reform of Investor-State Arbitration”
The Global Laboratory of Investment Law Reform Alternatives
The Limitations of Comparative Institutional Analysis
The Role of the State and the ISDS Trinity
Who's Afraid of Reform? Beware the Risk of Fragmentation