Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T15:42:06.025Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Advantages and limitations of representing groups in terms of recursive utilities

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 July 2022

Setayesh Radkani
Affiliation:
Department of Brain and Cognitive Sciences, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139, USAradkani@mit.edu; ajthomas@mit.edu; saxe@mit.edusaxelab.mit.edu
Ashley J. Thomas
Affiliation:
Department of Brain and Cognitive Sciences, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139, USAradkani@mit.edu; ajthomas@mit.edu; saxe@mit.edusaxelab.mit.edu
Rebecca Saxe
Affiliation:
Department of Brain and Cognitive Sciences, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139, USAradkani@mit.edu; ajthomas@mit.edu; saxe@mit.edusaxelab.mit.edu

Abstract

Group representations based on recursive utilities can be used to derive the same predictions as Pietraszewski in conflict situations. Additionally, these representations generalize to non-conflict situations, asymmetric relationships, and represent the stakes in a conflict. However, both proposals fail to represent asymmetries of power and responsibility and to account for generalizations from specific observed individuals to collections of non-observed individuals.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bruneau, E., Kteily, N., & Falk, E. (2018). Interventions highlighting hypocrisy reduce collective blame of Muslims for individual acts of violence and assuage anti-Muslim hostility. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 44(3), 430448.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fiske, A. P. (1992). The four elementary forms of sociality: Framework for a unified theory of social relations. Psychological Review, 99(4), 689.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kleiman-Weiner, M., Ho, M. K., Austerweil, J. L., Littman, M. L., & Tenenbaum, J. B. (2016). Coordinate to cooperate or compete: abstract goals and joint intentions in social interaction. In Proceedings of the 38th Annual Conference of the Cognitive Science Society.Google Scholar
Kleiman-Weiner, M., Saxe, R., & Tenenbaum, J. B. (2017). Learning a commonsense moral theory. Cognition, 167, 107123.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
O'Connor, C. (2019). The origins of unfairness: Social categories and cultural evolution. Oxford University Press, USA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, L. (2021). Adopted utility calculus: Origins of a concept of social affiliation. Perspectives on Psychological Science. https://doi.org/10.1177/17456916211048487Google Scholar